Lecture 3 - Decision Analysis
Lecture 3 - Decision Analysis
Example
Consider the following problem with three decision
alternatives and three states of nature with the following
payoff table representing profits:
States of Nature
s1
s2
s3
d1
4
4
Decisions d2
0
3
d3
1
5
Which decision do you choose?
-2
-1
-3
Problem Formulation
A decision problem is characterized by decision
alternatives, states of nature, and resulting payoffs.
The decision alternatives are the different possible
strategies the decision maker can employ.
The states of nature refer to future events, not under
the control of the decision maker, which may occur.
States of nature should be defined so that they are
mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive.
Payoff Tables
The consequence resulting from a specific combination
of a decision alternative and a state of nature is a payoff.
A table showing payoffs for all combinations of decision
alternatives and states of nature is a payoff table.
Payoffs can be expressed in terms of profit, cost, time,
distance or any other appropriate measure.
Optimistic Approach
The optimistic approach would be used by an
optimistic decision maker.
The decision with the largest possible payoff is
chosen.
If the payoff table was in terms of costs, the decision
with the lowest cost would be chosen.
Example
Consider the following problem with three decision
alternatives and three states of nature with the following
payoff table representing profits:
States of Nature
s1
s2
s3
d1
Decisions d2
d3
4
0
1
4
3
5
-2
-1
-3
Maximax
decision
Maximum
Decision
Payoff
d1
4
d2
3
d3
5
Maximax
payoff
Conservative Approach
The conservative approach would be used by a
conservative decision maker.
For each decision the minimum payoff is listed and
then the decision corresponding to the maximum of
these minimum payoffs is selected. (Hence, the
minimum possible payoff is maximized.)
If the payoff was in terms of costs, the maximum costs
would be determined for each decision and then the
decision corresponding to the minimum of these
maximum costs is selected. (Hence, the maximum
possible cost is minimized.)
Example
Consider the following problem with three decision
alternatives and three states of nature with the following
payoff table representing profits:
States of Nature
s1
s2
s3
d1
Decisions d2
d3
4
0
1
4
3
5
-2
-1
-3
Maximin
decision
Minimum
Decision
Payoff
d1
-2
d2
-1
d3
-3
Maximin
payoff
Example
Consider the following problem with three decision
alternatives and three states of nature with the following
payoff table representing profits:
States of Nature
s1
s2
s3
d1
Decisions d2
d3
4
0
1
4
3
5
-2
-1
-3
d1
d2
d3
s1
s2
s3
0
4
3
1
2
0
1
0
2
Minimax
decision
Decision
d1
d2
d3
Maximum
Regret
1
4
3
Minimax
regret
EV( d i ) P( s j )Vij
j 1
where:
Payoff Table
Average Number of Customers Per Hour
s1 = 80 s2 = 100 s3 = 120
Model A
Model B
Model C
probabilities
10,000
8,000
6,000
15,000
18,000
16,000
14,000
12,000
21,000
0.4
0.2
0.4
15,000
18,000
16,000
0.2
Decision Trees
A decision tree is a chronological
representation of the decision problem.
Branches leaving round nodes correspond to
different states of nature
Branches leaving square nodes correspond to
different decision alternatives.
At the end of each limb of the tree (each leaf) is the
payoff from that series of branches.
Model A
d1
Model B d2
Model C
= 14,000
Sensitivity Analysis
Sensitivity analysis can be used to determine how
changes to the following inputs affect the recommended
decision alternative:
probabilities for the states of nature
values of the payoffs
If a small change in the value of one of the inputs causes
a change in the recommended decision alternative, extra
effort and care should be taken in estimating the input
value.
EVPI example
Average Number of Customers Per Hour
s1 = 80 s2 = 100 s3 = 120
Model A
10,000
Model B
8,000
Model C
6,000
probabilities
0.4
15,000
18,000
16,000
0.2
EVPI example
EV if omniscient = .4(10,000)+.2(18,000)+.4(21,000) = 16,000
EV of Model C (best alternative) = 14,000
Expected value of perfect information = 2,000
If it cost 3,000 to do a study to clarify whether you were most likely to get 80,
100, or 120 customers/hour, would the study be worthwhile?
- No. Even perfect information could only add an expected value of
2,000.
What if it cost 1,000?
- Maybe. Yes, if your information would be very good; no, if it doesnt
improve your probability estimates enough to justify the cost.
Posterior Probabilities
Suppose you expect the survey to be favorable (high demand) with
probability 0.54, unfavorable w.p. 0.46.
Suppose the posterior probabilities are:
Favorable case:
Unfavorable case:
Check that the posteriors match the priors (0.4, 0.2, 0.4)
Pr(80) = Pr(favorable)*Pr(80 | favorable) + Pr(unfavorable)*Pr(80 | unfavorable)
= 0.54*0.148 + 0.46*0.696 = 0.40. Good!
(Otherwise you hold contradictory beliefs.) Check Pr(100), Pr(120) similarly.
Decision Tree
top half (case where survey is favorable)
s1 (.148)
d1
2
I1
(.54)
d2
d3
6
10,000
s2 (.185)
15,000
s3 (.667)
14,000
s1 (.148) 8,000
s2 (.185)
18,000
s3 (.667)
12,000
s1 (.148)
6,000
s2 (.185)
16,000
s3 (.667)
21,000
Decision Tree
bottom half (case where survey is unfavorable)
1
I2
(.46)
3
d1
d2
d3
9
s1 (.696)
10,000
s2 (.217)
15,000
s3 (.087)
14,000
s1 (.696)
8,000
s2 (.217)
18,000
s3 (.087)
12,000
6,000
s1 (.696)
s2 (.217)
16,000
s3 (.087)
21,000
Decision Tree
d1
17,855
I1
(.54)
d2
d3
1
d1
I2
(.46)
d2
3
11,433
EV = .148(10,000) + .185(15,000)
+ .667(14,000) = 13,593
EV = .148(6,000) + .185(16,000)
+.667(21,000) = 17,855
EV = .696(10,000) + .217(15,000)
+.087(14,000)= 11,433
EV = .696(8,000) + .217(18,000)
+ .087(12,000) = 10,554
EV = .696(6,000) + .217(16,000)
+.087(21,000) = 9,475
d3
Decision Tree
If the outcome of the survey is "favorable, choose C. Unfavorable, choose A.
Expected value with sample information =
.54(17,855) + .46(11,433) = 14,900.88
This is how much we expect to get if we do the survey, wait for the results, then
choose an alternative.
Without the survey, our best option was Model C. Recall that
EV of Model C = 14,000
utility
uRA
1.00
0.75
0.50
0.25
0.00
-5
10
15
Profit
[millions of pounds]
42
Utility
In general, utility (how much you care about something) is not
linear.
size of
business
profitability
short
term
long
term
market
share
growth
flexibility
vMS
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
5
7.5
10
12.5
15
17.5
20
22.5
25
27.5
30
vMS
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
5
7.5
10
12.5
15
17.5
20
22.5
25
27.5
30
Score
100
60
40
0
47
vMS
100
90
Partial Performances
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
5
long term
sustainability
7.5
10
12.5
15
17.5
20
22.5
25
27.5
30
profitability
short
term
long
term
size of
business
market
share
growth
100
60
40
flexibility
48
Max Profitability
[profit over 2 years]
$2,000 mi
S2
S1
40%
32%
$500 mi
S1
S1 is preferred to S2
S1 is indifferent to S2
20%
49
Making Trade-Offs
Associate a swing weight with each attribute
The value of a decision alternative is the sum of the utilities for each
attribute, weighted by the swing weights
Suppose alternative A had 30% market share (value 100) and flexibility
possible (value 40).
Suppose market share is 2 times as important to you as flexibility,
leading you to choose swing weights of 2 and 1.
The value of decision A would be 2*100 + 1*40, plus similar contributions
from the other attributes.
The best decision is the one with the largest weighted utility.
profitability
34%
short
term
66%
long
term
62%
market
share
59
47
46
6%
38%
growth
flexibility
100
c
0
51
Game theory
MA402
OR409
game theory
auctions and game theory