0% found this document useful (0 votes)
51 views35 pages

Purnanandam 2010

1) The originate-to-distribute model of mortgage lending became popular before the subprime crisis, allowing banks to sell loans to third parties rather than hold them. However, this reduced banks' incentives to properly screen borrowers and originated loans. 2) Banks highly involved in originate-to-distribute lending originated poor quality mortgages that were riskier than observable borrower characteristics explained. This supports the view that banks did not adequately screen borrowers when not holding the loans. 3) When the secondary mortgage market collapsed in 2007, banks with high originate-to-distribute lending were left holding large quantities of risky, poor quality loans, contributing to higher mortgage defaults and chargeoffs.

Uploaded by

Saiful Amri
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
Download as pdf or txt
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
51 views35 pages

Purnanandam 2010

1) The originate-to-distribute model of mortgage lending became popular before the subprime crisis, allowing banks to sell loans to third parties rather than hold them. However, this reduced banks' incentives to properly screen borrowers and originated loans. 2) Banks highly involved in originate-to-distribute lending originated poor quality mortgages that were riskier than observable borrower characteristics explained. This supports the view that banks did not adequately screen borrowers when not holding the loans. 3) When the secondary mortgage market collapsed in 2007, banks with high originate-to-distribute lending were left holding large quantities of risky, poor quality loans, contributing to higher mortgage defaults and chargeoffs.

Uploaded by

Saiful Amri
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1/ 35

Originate-to-distribute Model and the

Subprime Mortgage Crisis


Amiyatosh Purnanandam

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Ross School of Business, University of Michigan

An originate-to-distribute (OTD) model of lending, where the originator of a loan sells


it to various third parties, was a popular method of mortgage lending before the onset
of the subprime mortgage crisis. We show that banks with high involvement in the OTD
market during the pre-crisis period originated excessively poor-quality mortgages. This
result is not explained away by differences in observable borrower quality, geographical
location of the property, or the cost of capital of high- and low-OTD banks. Instead, our
evidence supports the view that the originating banks did not expend resources in screen-
ing their borrowers. The effect of OTD lending on poor mortgage quality is stronger for
capital-constrained banks. Overall, we provide evidence that lack of screening incentives
coupled with leverage-induced risk-taking behavior significantly contributed to the current
subprime mortgage crisis. (JEL G11, G12, G13, G14)

The recent crisis in the mortgage market is having an enormous impact on the
world economy. While the popular press has presented a number of anecdotes
and case studies, a body of academic research is fast evolving to understand
the precise causes and consequences of this crisis (see Greenlaw et al. 2008;
Brunnermeier 2009). Our study contributes to this growing literature by an-
alyzing the effect of banks’ participation in the originate-to-distribute (OTD)
method of lending on the crisis.
As a part of their core operation, banks develop considerable expertise in
screening and monitoring their borrowers to minimize the costs of adverse
selection and moral hazard. It is possible that they are not able to take full ad-
vantage of this expertise due to market incompleteness, regulatory reasons, or
some other frictions. For example, regulatory capital requirements and frictions

I thank Sugato Bhattacharya, Uday Rajan, and George Pennacchi for extensive discussions and detailed com-
ments on the article. I want to thank an anonymous referee, Franklin Allen, Heitor Almeida, Sreedhar Bharath,
Charles Calomiris, Sudheer Chava, Douglas Diamond, Gary Fissel, Scott Frame, Chris James, Han Kim, Paul
Kupiec, Pete Kyle, M. P. Narayanan, Paolo Pasquariello, Raghuram Rajan, Joao Santos, Antoinette Schoar,
Amit Seru, Matt Spiegel, Bhaskaran Swaminathan, Sheridan Titman, Anjan Thakor, Peter Tufano, Haluk Unal,
Otto Van Hemert, Paul Willen, and seminar participants at the Board of Governors, Washington, D.C., FDIC,
Michigan State University, Loyola College, University of Texas at Dallas, University of Wisconsin-Madison,
Washington University, York University, AFA 2010, WFA 2009, FIRS 2010, Bank of Portugal Financial In-
termediation Conference 2009, and Texas Finance Festival 2009 for valuable suggestions. Kuncheng Zheng
provided excellent research assistance. I gratefully acknowledge financial support from the FDIC’s Center for
Financial Research. All remaining errors are mine. Send correspondence to Amiyatosh Purnanandam, Ross
School of Business, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 48109; telephone: (734) 764-6886. E-mail: amiy-
atos@umich.edu.

c The Author 2010. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Society for Financial Studies.
All rights reserved. For Permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oup.com.
doi:10.1093/rfs/hhq106 Advance Access publication October 14, 2010
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

in raising external capital might prohibit a bank from lending up to the first-best
level (Stein 1998). Financial innovations naturally arise as a market response to
these frictions (Tufano 2003; Allen and Gale 1994). The originate-to-distribute
(OTD) model of lending, where the originator of loans sells them to third par-
ties, emerged as a solution to some of these frictions. This model allows the

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


originating financial institution to achieve better risk-sharing with the rest of
the economy,1 economize on regulatory capital, and achieve better liquidity
risk management.2
These benefits of the OTD model come at a cost. As the lending practice
shifts from an originate-to-hold to an originate-to-distribute model, it begins
to interfere with the originating banks’ screening and monitoring incentives
(Pennacchi 1988; Gorton and Pennacchi 1995; Petersen and Rajan 1994;
Parlour and Plantin 2008). It is this cost of the OTD model that lies at the
root of our analysis. Banks make lending decisions based on a number of bor-
rower characteristics. While some of these characteristics are easy to credibly
communicate to third parties, there are soft pieces of information that cannot
be easily verified by parties other than the originating institution itself. Thus,
as the originating institution sheds the credit risk, and as the distance between
the originator and the ultimate holder of risk increases, loan officers’ ex ante
incentives to collect soft information decrease (see Stein 2002 and Rajan, Seru,
and Vig 2009). If the ultimate holders of credit risk do not completely appre-
ciate the true credit risk of mortgage loans, then it is easy to see the resulting
dilution in the originator’s screening incentives. However, it is not a neces-
sary condition for the dilution in screening standards to occur. For example, if
the cost of communicating soft information is so high that all originators are
pooled together by the outside investors, then the originator’s ex ante screening
incentive goes down even without pricing mistakes by the ultimate investors.
The screening incentives can deteriorate further if credit-rating agencies make
mistakes, as some observers have argued, in assessing the true credit risk of
mortgage-backed securities.
Our key hypothesis is that banks with aggressive involvement in the OTD
market had lower screening incentives, which in turn resulted in the origi-
nation of loans with excessively poor soft information by these banks. The
OTD model of lending allowed them to benefit from the origination fees with-
out bearing the credit risk of the borrowers. As long as the secondary market
for mortgage sale was functioning normally, they were able to easily offload
these loans to third parties.3 When the secondary mortgage market came under

1 Allen and Carletti (2006) analyze conditions under which credit-risk transfer from banking to some other sector
leads to risk-sharing benefits. They also argue that under certain conditions, these risk-transfer tools can lead to
welfare-decreasing outcomes.
2 See Drucker and Puri (2005) for a survey of different theories behind loan sales.

3 The mortgage market was functioning normally until the first quarter of 2007. In March 2007, several subprime
mortgage lenders filed for bankruptcy, providing some early signals of the oncoming mortgage crisis. The sign of
stress in this market became visibly clear by the middle of 2007 (Greenlaw, Hatzius, Kashyap, and Shin 2008).

1882
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

pressure in the middle of 2007, banks with a higher volume of OTD loans were
stuck with large quantities of relatively inferior-quality mortgage loans. It can
take about two to three quarters from the origination to the sale of these loans in
the secondary market (Gordon and D’Silva 2008). In addition, the originators
typically guarantee the loan performance for the first 90 days of loans (Mishkin

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


2008). If banks with a high volume of OTD loans in the pre-disruption pe-
riod were originating loans of inferior quality, then in the immediate post-
disruption period, such banks are likely to be left with a disproportionately
large quantity of poor loans. We use the sudden drop in liquidity in the sec-
ondary mortgage market to identify the effect of OTD lending on mortgage
quality.
We define the period up to the first quarter of 2007 as the pre-disruption
period, and later quarters as post-disruption. We first confirm that banks with
a large quantity of origination in the immediate pre-disruption period were
unable to sell their OTD loans in the post-disruption period. We then show
that banks with higher participation with the OTD model in the pre-disruption
period had significantly higher mortgage chargeoffs and defaults by their
borrowers in the immediate post-disruption period. In addition, the mortgage
chargeoffs and borrower defaults are higher for those banks that were unable
to sell their pre-disruption OTD loans; i.e., for banks that were left with large
quantities of undesired mortgage portfolios.
Overall, these results suggest that OTD loans were of inferior quality, and
banks that were stuck with these loans in the post-disruption period had dis-
proportionately higher chargeoffs and borrower defaults. In order to provide
convincing support for the diluted screening incentives hypothesis, it is im-
portant to rule out the effect of observable differences in the quality of loans
issued by high- and low-OTD banks on mortgage default rate. We conduct sev-
eral tests using detailed loan-level data from the Home Mortgage Disclosure
Act (HMDA) to address this issue. In these tests, we compare the default rate
of high- and low-OTD banks that are matched along several dimensions of
borrowers’ observable default risk, properties’ location, and the bank’s char-
acteristics. We show that our results remain strong in the matched subsamples.
Thus, the effect of OTD lending on mortgage default rates is not an artifact of
observable differences in the borrowers’ credit risk, the geographical location
of high- and low-OTD banks, or differences in the originating bank’s other
characteristics, such as size and cost of capital.
We continue our investigation by analyzing the interest rates charged by
high- and low-OTD banks during the pre-disruption period. If a bank screens
its borrowers carefully on unobservable dimensions, then it is more likely to
charge different interest rates to observationally similar borrowers (see Rajan,
Seru, and Vig 2009). Therefore, we expect to find a wider distribution of inter-
est rates for the same set of observable characteristics for a bank that screens
its borrowers more actively. Based on this idea, we compare the distribution of
interest rates charged by the high- and low-OTD banks. Consistent with the lax

1883
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

screening hypothesis, we find evidence of tighter distribution for the high-OTD


banks in our sample.
In our final test, we focus on the determinants of poor screening by the high-
OTD banks. We find that the effect of pre-disruption OTD lending on mortgage
default rates is stronger among banks with lower regulatory capital. If banks

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


used the OTD model of lending in response to binding capital constraints, then
banks with a lower capital base should do no worse than the well-capitalized
banks. In contrast, theoretical models such as Thakor (1996) and Holmstrom
and Tirole (1997) suggest that banks with lower capital have a lower screening
incentive due to the risk-shifting problem. Our results support the presence
of lax screening incentives behind the origination of such loans. We also find
that the effect of OTD loans on mortgage default is concentrated among banks
with a lower dependence on demand deposits.4 The result supports the view
that demand deposits worked as a governance device for commercial banks,
as argued by Calomoris and Kahn (1991), Flannery (1994), and Diamond and
Rajan (2001). Our study shows that banks that were primarily funded by non-
demandable or market-based wholesale debt were the main originators of poor-
quality OTD loans.
There is a growing literature in this area, with important contributions from
Keys et al. 2010; Mian and Sufi 2010; Loutskina and Strahan 2008; Doms,
Furlong, and Krainer 2007; Mayer and Pence 2008; Dell’Ariccia, Igan, and
Laeven 2008; Demyanyk and Van Hemert 2009; and Titman and Tsyplakov
2010. We make three unique contributions to the literature. This is one of
the first academic studies that compares default rates of banks that originated
loans to sell to third parties with banks that originated loans for their own
portfolios. Our findings complement those of Keys et al. (2010), who ana-
lyze default rates of securitized loans above and below the FICO score of
620. In addition to the advantage of comparing sold versus retained loans,
our analysis also shows that the dilution in screening standards was not con-
fined to a particular range of borrowers’ FICO scores. Instead, it was a far
more widespread phenomenon that occurred throughout the banking sector.
Second, we focus on lending decisions of institutions that are directly originat-
ing loans from borrowers or through their brokers. Thus, our study analyzes
the screening behavior of economic agents that are directly responsible for
originating loans at the front end of the lending-securitization channel. Third,
our study advances the literature by showing that a bank’s capital position
and reliance on non-demandable debt have significant effects on its screening
incentives.
Overall, our findings have important implications for banking regulations. In
addition, we contribute to the credit-risk pricing literature by showing that in
an information-sensitive asset market, the issuer’s capital position and liability

4 Since the capital structure and the demand deposit mix of large banks are generally very different from those of
the small banks, we pay careful attention to the effect of bank size in these tests.

1884
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

structure have important implications for the pricing of assets in the secondary
market. It is important to note that our results come from a period of turmoil
in the financial markets. To draw strong policy implications, one obviously
has to compare these costs of securitization with the potential benefits of risk-
management tools (Stulz 1984; Smith and Stulz 1985; Froot, Scharfstein, and

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Stein 1993; Froot and Stein 1998; Drucker and Puri 2009).5 It is also worth
pointing out that the role of other macroeconomic factors, such as the aggregate
borrowing and savings rate and monetary policies across the globe, cannot be
ignored as a potential explanation for the crisis (see Allen 2009). Our study is
essentially cross-sectional in nature, which limits our ability to comment on
the role of these macroeconomic factors.
The rest of the article is organized as follows. Section 1 describes the data
and provides descriptive statistics. Section 2 presents empirical results relat-
ing OTD market participation to mortgage defaults. Section 3 provides the
matched sample results. Section 4 explores the linkages with capital position
and liability structure, and Section 5 concludes.

1. Data
We use two sources of data for our study: the call report database for bank in-
formation and the HMDA (Home Mortgage Disclosure Act) database for loan
details. All Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)-insured commer-
cial banks are required to file call reports with the regulators on a quarterly
basis. These reports contain detailed information on the bank’s income state-
ment, balance-sheet items, and off-balance-sheet activities. The items required
to be filed in this report change over time to reflect the changing nature of bank-
ing business. As the mortgage sale and securitization activities grew in recent
years, there have been concomitant improvements in the quality of reporting
with respect to these items as well.
Beginning with the third quarter of 2006, banks started to report two key
items regarding their mortgage activities: (a) the origination of 1–4 family
residential mortgages during the quarter with a purpose to resell in the market;
and (b) the extent of 1–4 family residential mortgages actually sold during the
quarter. These variables allow us to measure the extent of participation in the
OTD market as well as the extent of loans that were actually offloaded by a
bank in a given quarter. Both items are provided in schedule RC-P of the call
report. This schedule is required to be filed by banks with $1 billion or more in
total assets and by smaller banks if they exceed $10 million in their mortgage-
selling activities. The data, in effect, are available for all banks that participate
significantly in the OTD market.

5 See also Ashcraft and Santos (2008) for a study on the costs and benefits of credit default swaps, and Gande and
Saunders (2007) for the effect of the secondary loan sales market on the bank-specialness.

1885
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

We construct our key measure of OTD activity as the ratio of loans origi-
nated for resale during the quarter scaled by the beginning of the quarter mort-
gage loans of the bank. This ratio captures the extent of a bank’s participation
in the OTD market as a fraction of its overall mortgage portfolio. We measure
the extent of selling in the OTD market as the ratio of loans sold during the

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


quarter scaled by the mortgage loans from the beginning of the quarter.
We obtain two measures of mortgage quality from the call reports: (1)
chargeoffs on 1–4 family residential mortgages; and (2) non-performing assets
(NPAs) for this category; i.e., mortgage loans that are past due or delinquent.
We use net chargeoffs (net of recoveries) as the first proxy of loan quality. It
measures the immediate effect of mortgage defaults on a bank’s profitability.
However, chargeoffs may be subject to the reporting bank’s discretionary ac-
counting rules. Mortgage NPAs, on the other hand, are free from this bias and
provide a more direct measure of the borrowers’ default rate.
We get information on the banks’ assets, profitability, mortgage loans, liq-
uidity ratio, capital ratios, and several other variables from the call report. It
is important to construct these variables in a consistent manner across quar-
ters since the call report’s reporting format changes somewhat over time. Our
study spans only seven quarters—from 2006Q3, the first quarter with OTD
data available, to 2008Q1. The reporting requirement has been fairly stable
over this time period, and we check every quarter’s format to ensure that our
data are consistent over time. We provide detailed information on the variables
and construction of key ratios in the Appendix.
We obtain detailed loan-level information from the HMDA database. The
HMDA was enacted by Congress in 1975 to improve reporting requirements
in the mortgage lending business. The HMDA database is an annual database
that contains loan-by-loan information on borrower quality, applicant’s de-
mographic information, and interest rate on the loan if it exceeds a certain
threshold. We match the call report and HMDA database for 2006 to obtain in-
formation on the quality of borrowers and geographical location of loans made
by banks during the pre-disruption period.

1.1 Descriptive statistics


Our sample consists of all banks with available data on mortgage origination
for resale from 2006Q3 to 2008Q1. We intersect this sample with banks cov-
ered in the HMDA database in 2006. We create a balanced panel of banks,
requiring the sample bank to be present in all seven quarters. This filter re-
moves only a few banks and does not change any of our results. We impose
this filter because we want to exploit the variation in mortgage default rates of
the same bank over time as the mortgage market passed through the period of
stress.
We begin the discussion of descriptive statistics with a few charts. In
Figure 1, we plot the quarterly average of loans originated for resale as a

1886
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Figure 1
Mortgage originated for distribution over time
The figure plots the ratio of OTD loans to total mortgages on a quarterly basis. We plot the average value of this
ratio across all banks with available information in the sample. Quarter zero corresponds to the quarter ending
on March 31, 2007.

fraction of the bank’s outstanding mortgage loans (measured at the beginning


of the quarter). This ratio measures the bank’s desired level of credit-risk trans-
fer through the OTD model. The ratio averaged just below 30% during 2006Q3
and 2006Q4 and dropped to about 20% in the subsequent quarters. The drop
is consistent with the popular belief that the OTD market came under tremen-
dous stress during this period. Figure 2 plots the quarterly average of loans sold
scaled by the beginning of the quarter loans outstanding. This measures the ex-
tent of credit-risk transfer that the bank was actually able to achieve during the
quarter. There is a noticeable decline in the extent of loan sales starting with
2007Q1. As we show later, the decline was especially pronounced in banks that
were aggressively participating in the OTD market in or before 2007Q1. Over-
all, these graphs show that the extent of loan origination and loans transferred
to other parties came down appreciably over this time period.
Figure 3 plots the average percentage chargeoff on 1–4 family residential
mortgage loans on a quarterly basis. As expected, the quarterly chargeoffs
have increased steadily since 2007Q1. The chargeoffs increased fourfold from
2007Q1 to 2007Q4—a very significant increase for highly leveraged finan-
cial institutions. We find a similar trend for non-performing mortgages as well
(unreported).
Table 1 provides the descriptive statistics of other key variables used in the
study. We winsorize data at 1% from both tails to minimize the effects of out-
liers. The average bank in our sample has an asset base of $5.9 billion (median
$1.1 billion). These numbers show that our sample represents relatively large

1887
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Figure 2
Mortgage sold over time
The figure plots the extent of loans sold as a fraction of mortgages outstanding as of the beginning of the quarter.
We plot the average value of this ratio across all banks with available information in the sample. Quarter zero
corresponds to the quarter ending on March 31, 2007.

Figure 3
Mortgage chargeoff over time
The figure plots the average net chargeoff as a percentage of mortgage outstanding on a quarterly basis. Quarter
zero corresponds to the quarter ending on March 31, 2007.

banks, due to the fact that we require data on OTD mortgage origination and
sale for a bank to be available to be included in our sample. We provide the
distribution of other key variables in the table. These numbers are in line with
other studies involving large bank samples.

1888
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

Table 1
Summary statistics
variable N mean p50 min max
ta 5397.00 5.92 1.05 0.06 168.65
mortgage/ta 5397.00 0.17 0.15 0.01 0.49
cil/ta 5397.00 0.11 0.10 0.00 0.39

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


td/ta 5397.00 0.78 0.80 0.44 0.92
dd/td 5397.00 0.09 0.08 0.01 0.33
leverage 6636.00 0.90 0.91 0.77 0.94
nii/ta 5397.00 0.89 0.87 0.32 1.51
chargeoff(%) 5397.00 0.04 0.00 −0.07 0.79
npa/ta(%) 5397.00 0.73 0.44 0.00 5.40
mortnpa(%) 5397.00 2.03 1.35 0.00 13.86
tier1cap 5397.00 0.11 0.10 0.07 0.29
liquid 5397.00 0.15 0.12 0.02 0.50
absgap 5397.00 0.14 0.11 0.00 0.51
preotd 771.00 0.23 0.05 0.00 3.06

This table provides the summary statistics of key variables used in the study. All variables are computed using
call report data for seven quarters starting from 2006Q3 and ending in 2008Q1. We provide the number of
observations (N), mean, median, minimum, and maximum values for each variable. ta is total assets in billions
of dollars; mortgage/ta is the ratio of 1–4 family residential mortgages outstanding to total assets; cil/ta is the
ratio of commercial and industrial loans to total assets; td/ta is the ratio of total deposits to total assets; dd/td is
the ratio of demand deposits to total deposits; nii/ta is the ratio of net interest income to total assets; chargeoff
measures the chargeoff on mortgage portfolio (net of recoveries) as a percentage of mortgage assets; npa/ta
is the ratio of non-performing assets to total assets; mortnpa is the ratio of non-performing mortgages to total
mortgages; tier1cap measures the ratio of tier-one capital to risk-adjusted assets; liquid is the bank’s liquid assets
to total assets ratio, absgap is the absolute value of one-year maturity gap as a fraction of total assets. preotd
measures the originate-to-distribute loans, i.e., mortgages originated with a purpose to sell, as a fraction of total
mortgages. This variable is constructed at the bank level based on its average quarterly values during 2006Q3,
2006Q4, and 2007Q1.

Figure 4 provides a graphical preview of our results. We take the average


value of OTD ratio for every bank during 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1;
i.e., during quarters prior to the serious disruption in the market. We call this
variable preotd.6 We classify banks into high- or low-OTD groups based on
whether they fall into the top or bottom one-third of the preotd distribution. We
track mortgage chargeoffs of these two groups of banks over quarters and plot
them in Figure 4. Consistent with our earlier graph on the aggregate charge-
offs, this figure shows that both groups have experienced a significant increase
in chargeoffs over time. However, there is a remarkable difference in their
slopes. While both groups started at similar levels of chargeoffs in 2006Q3
and they show parallel trends before the beginning of the crisis, the high-OTD
group’s chargeoffs increased five times by the end of the sample period as
compared with a significantly lower increase of about two to three times for
the low-OTD group. We also plot the fitted difference between the two groups
over time. The fitted difference measures the difference in the rate of increase
in chargeoffs across the two groups and therefore gives a graphical snapshot
of the difference-in-difference estimation results. The fitted difference shows a

6 Our results are robust to alternative ways of constructing this variable; for example, by averaging over only
2006Q3 and 2006Q4 or by only taking 2007Q1 value as the measure of preotd.

1889
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Figure 4
Mortgage chargeoff and OTD participation
The figure plots the average net chargeoff (as a percentage of mortgage outstanding) on the bank’s mortgage
portfolio across two groups of banks sorted on the basis of their participation in the OTD market prior to March
31, 2007.

remarkable linear increase over this time period. The difference in default rate
becomes especially high after a couple of quarters from the onset of the crisis.
In summary, we find that banks with higher OTD participation before the
subprime mortgage crisis increased their chargeoffs significantly more than
banks with lower OTD. Are these differences significant after accounting for
differences in bank characteristics and the quality of borrowers they face? And
why does this difference exist across the two groups? We explore these ques-
tions through formal econometric tests in the rest of the article.

2. Mortgage Default Rate and OTD


We first establish that there was a significant drop in the extent of mortgages
sold in the secondary market in the post-disruption period. We follow this up
with our main test that examines the relationship between a bank’s mortgage
default rate and the extent of its participation in the OTD market.

2.1 Empirical design and identification strategy


Our key argument is that banks with aggressive involvement in the OTD model
of lending did not actively screen their borrowers along the soft informa-
tion dimension. The OTD model allowed them to benefit from the origination
fees without bearing the ultimate credit risk of the borrowers. These banks
originated large amounts of loans with inferior soft information, which were
subsequently sold to investors. As long as the secondary loan market had

1890
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

enough liquidity, banks were able to offload their originated loans without
any disruption. The delay from origination to the final sale of these loans did
not impose significant credit risk on the originating banks during normal pe-
riods. However, when the secondary mortgage market came under pressure
in the middle of 2007, banks with high-OTD loans were stuck with dispro-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


portionately large amounts of inferior-quality mortgage loans. The problem
was exacerbated by the early pay default warranties that the sellers of OTD
loans typically provide to their buyers for the first 90 days after the loan sale
(Mishkin 2008). Therefore, immediately after the liquidity shock of summer
2007, these banks were left with disproportionately large amounts of OTD
mortgage loans that they had originated with an intention to sell but could not
sell. If these loans had relatively lower screening standards, then we expect
to find relatively higher mortgage default rates for high-OTD banks in quar-
ters immediately following the onset of the crisis as compared with otherwise
similar low-OTD banks that originated most of their loans with an intention to
keep them on their balance sheets.
To test this hypothesis in an idealized experimental setting, we need two ran-
domly selected groups of banks that are identical in every respect except for
their involvement in the OTD method of lending. To be more precise, we want
to compare banks with varying intensity of OTD lending that have made loans
to borrowers with observationally similar risk characteristics. This will allow
us to estimate the effect of OTD lending on the screening efforts of banks along
the soft information dimension without contaminating the results from differ-
ences in observable risk characteristics of the borrowers. Because we have
only observational data, we control for these differences by including several
bank and borrower characteristics in the regression model. More importantly,
we conduct our tests in a difference-in-difference setting with carefully cho-
sen matched samples of high- and low-OTD banks. In these tests, we attempt
to find pairs of banks that are similar and have made loans to observationally
similar borrowers before the crisis. Then we exploit differences along the OTD
dimension in these samples to estimate the effect of OTD lending on screening
efforts.

2.1.1 Extent of mortgage resale. Since our identification strategy relies on


banks’ inability to sell their loans in the secondary markets, we first document
evidence in support of this argument. We estimate the following model:
k=K
X
soldit = β0 + β1 aftert + β2 preotdi + β3 aftert ∗ preotdi + β X it + it .
k=1
soldit measures bank i’s mortgage sale as a fraction of its total mortgage loans
at the beginning of quarter t.7 As described earlier, preotdi is a time-invariant

7 Our results are similar if we add the mortgages originated during the quarter in the denominator.

1891
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

variable that measures the extent of bank i’s participation in the OTD market
prior to the disruption in this market in the middle of 2007. We expect to find
a positive and significant coefficient on this variable because banks with large
OTD loans, almost by construction, are more likely to sell large quantities
of these loans in the secondary market. a f tert is an indicator variable that

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


equals one for quarters after 2007Q1, and zero otherwise. The coefficient on
this variable captures the difference in mortgages sold before and after the
crisis. The coefficient on the interaction term pr eotdi ∗ a f tert is the estimate
of interest. This coefficient measures the change in the intensity of loans sold
around the disruption period across banks with different degrees of pr eotd.
We control for several bank characteristics denoted by vector X it to account
for the effect of bank size, liquidity, maturity gap, and the ratio of commercial
and industrial loans to total assets. More importantly, we also include a variable
pr emor tgage that measures the extent of mortgages made by the bank during
the pre-disruption period. This variable is computed as the average of the ratio
of mortgage loans to total assets during 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. We
include this variable and its interaction with a f ter to separate the effect of
high-mortgage banks from the high-OTD banks.8
To provide a benchmark specification, we first estimate this model using the
OLS method. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level to account for
correlated errors across all quarters for the same bank (see Bertrand, Duflo,
and Mullainathan 2004). In the OLS model, we include indicator variables for
the bank’s state to control for state-specific differences in mortgage activities.
Results are provided in Model 1 of Table 2. As expected, we find a large and
positive coefficient on the pr eotd variable. The coefficient on the interaction
of a f ter and pr eotd is negative and highly significant. In this specification,
we find a positive coefficient on the a f ter dummy variable. In unreported tests,
we estimate an OLS regression of soldit on a f ter and obtain a coefficient of
−0.031(t − stat = −1.97) on a f ter . Therefore, the sharp decline in the loan
resale is concentrated within the set of high pr eotd banks.
We provide bank fixed-effect estimation results in Models 2 and 3 of Table 2.
This estimation method is more appealing, as it controls for bank-specific un-
observable effects and allows us to more precisely estimate the effect of disrup-
tion in the mortgage market on the high-OTD banks. pr eotd and pr emor tgage
are omitted from this model because they are captured in the bank fixed ef-
fects. Our identification comes from the interaction of a f ter with pr eotd.
In Model 2, we find a significant negative coefficient on the interaction term,
which confirms that banks with large OTD loans in the pre-disruption period
suffered a significant decline in mortgage resale during the post-disruption pe-
riod. In unreported tests, we estimate this model without the interaction term
a f ter ∗ pr eotd and find a significant negative coefficient on a f ter (coefficient

8 Our results are similar without the inclusion of the pr emor tgage variable in the regression models.

1892
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

Table 2
Intensity of mortgages sold
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat
preotd 0.9591 (54.64)

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


premortgage 0.0403 (0.85)
after 0.0273 (1.95) 0.0182 (1.23) 0.0205 (1.24)
after*preotd −0.1889 (−3.34) −0.2037 (−3.74) −0.2120 (−3.86)
after*premortgage 0.0163 (0.21) 0.0235 (0.29) 0.0428 (0.49)
logta −0.0031 (−0.54) 0.1475 (2.88) 0.1575 (2.44)
cil/ta −0.0248 (−0.22) −0.8606 (−2.74) −0.7744 (−2.40)
liquid 0.0339 (0.48) −0.0292 (−0.21) 0.0570 (0.38)
absgap −0.0320 (−0.55) 0.2866 (2.79) 0.3171 (2.82)
R2 0.8156 0.9039 0.9054
N 4476 4476 4100
State dummies Yes No No
Bank fixed effect No Yes Yes
Exclude large banks No No Yes

This table provides the regression results of the following model:

k=K
X
soldit = β0 + β1 a f tert + β2 pr eotdi + β3 a f tert ∗ pr eotdi + β X + it .
k=1

The dependent variable, soldit , measures bank i ’s mortgage sale as a fraction of its total mortgage loans at the
beginning of quarter t . a f tert is a dummy variable that is set to zero for quarters before and including 2007Q1,
and one after that. pr eotdi is the average value of OTD mortgages to total mortgages during quarters 2006Q3,
2006Q4, and 2007Q1. X stands for a set of control variables. Model 1 is estimated using the OLS method.
Models 2 and 3 are estimated with bank fixed effects. Model 3 excludes banks with more than $10 billion in
assets. These models omit pr eotd and pr emor tgage as right-hand-side variables since they remain constant
across all seven quarters for a given bank. premortgage is the average ratio of mortgage assets to total assets
for 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. logta measures the log of total assets; cil/ta is the ratio of commercial and
industrial loans to total assets; liquid is the bank’s liquid assets to total asset ratio; absgap is the absolute value of
one-year maturity gap as a fraction of total assets. Adjusted R-squared and number of observations are provided
in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.

estimate of −0.0251 with t-statistics of −2.74). These findings show that the
decline in mortgage resale is concentrated among high pr eotd banks. In Model
3, we re-estimate the fixed-effect model after removing banks with more than
$10 billion in asset size from the sample because it is often argued that large
money-centric banks have a different business model than regional and local
banks. We find that our results are equally strong after excluding these large
banks from the sample.
These results are economically significant as well. For example, a one-
standard-deviation increase in OTD lending prior to the disruption results in
a decline of 10% in selling intensity after the crisis based on the estimates of
Model 2. Overall, these results are consistent with our assertion that the dis-
ruption in the mortgage market created warehousing risk for the banks, which
in turn led to an accumulation of undesired loans; i.e., loans that were initially
intended to be sold but could not be sold due to an unexpected decline in the
market conditions.

1893
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

2.2 Mortgage defaults


We now estimate the effect of OTD lending on a bank’s quarterly mortgage
default rates with the following bank fixed-effect regression model:
defaultit = μi + β1 aftert + β2 aftert ∗ preotdi + β3 aftert ∗ premortgagei

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


k=K
X
+ β X it + it .
k=1

The dependent variable of this model measures the default rate of the mortgage
portfolio of bank i in quarter t. We use two measures of default: net-chargeoffs
and non-performing mortgages; i.e., mortgages that are in default for more than
30 days. We scale them by the bank’s total mortgage loans measured as of the
beginning of the quarter. μi stands for bank fixed effects, and X it is a vec-
tor of bank characteristics.9 The coefficient on the a f ter variable captures the
time trend in default rate before and after the mortgage crisis. The coefficient
on the interaction term (i.e., a f tert ∗ pr eotdi ) measures the change in char-
geoffs/NPAs around the crisis period across banks with varying intensities of
participation in the OTD market prior to the crisis. Said differently, β2 mea-
sures the change in default rate for banks that originated loans primarily to sell
them to third parties, as compared with the corresponding change for banks
that originated loans primarily to retain them on their own balance sheets. We
include the interaction of a f ter with pr emor tgage to ensure that the relation-
ship between OTD loans and mortgage performance is not simply an artifact
of higher involvement in mortgage lending by higher OTD banks.10
We control for a host of bank characteristics that can potentially affect the
quality of mortgage loans. We control for the bank’s size by including the log
of total assets in the regression model. We include the ratio of commercial and
industrial loans to total assets to control for the broad business mix of the bank.
A measure of the 12-month maturity gap is included to control for the interest-
rate risk faced by the banks. Finally, we include the ratio of liquid assets to
total assets to control for the liquidity position. The last three variables broadly
capture the extent and nature of credit risk, interest-rate risk, and liquidity risk
faced by the banks.
Table 3 provides the results. We provide results for the entire sample in
Models 1 and 2. In Models 3 and 4, we exclude large banks with asset size
more than $10 billion from the sample. We find that the extent of participation
in the OTD market during the pre-disruption period has a significant effect

9 In an alternative specification, we also estimate this model without bank fixed effects (similar to the one de-
scribed in the previous section for the extent of mortgage resale). The advantage of this model is that it also
allows us to estimate the coefficient on pr eotd . However, we prefer the bank fixed-effect approach as it allows
us to control for unobservable factors that are time-invariant and unique to a bank. All key results remain similar
for the alternative econometric model.
10 We re-estimate these models without including the interaction of a f ter and pr emor tgage and obtain similar
results.

1894
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

Table 3
Mortgage defaults
All Banks Excludes Large Banks
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Chargeoffs NPA Chargeoffs NPA

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Dependent Var: Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat
after 0.0116 (1.91) 0.3411 (3.03) 0.0134 (2.03) 0.3076 (2.52)
after*preotd 0.0420 (2.76) 0.4439 (2.44) 0.0428 (2.76) 0.4015 (2.21)
after*premortgage 0.0060 (0.21) 0.6600 (1.22) −0.0062 (−0.20) 0.4261 (0.82)
logta 0.0925 (4.15) 0.2266 (0.51) 0.0776 (2.67) 0.6896 (1.42)
cil/ta 0.2010 (1.65) 2.6103 (1.37) 0.1662 (1.32) 2.2626 (1.13)
liquid 0.0745 (1.24) 1.3732 (0.90) 0.1089 (1.64) −0.1540 (−0.14)
absgap −0.0672 (−1.59) −3.2639 (−3.85) −0.0742 (−1.64) −3.1248 (−3.66)

R2 0.3805 0.7297 0.3621 0.7135


N 5397 5397 4977 4977

This table provides the regression results of the following fixed-effects model:
k=K
X
defaultit = μi + β1 aftert + β2 aftert ∗ preotdi + β X + it .
k=1
The dependent variable, de f aultit , is measured by either the mortgage chargeoffs or the non-performing mort-
gages (scaled by the outstanding mortgage loans) of bank i during quarter t . a f tert is a dummy variable that is
set to zero for quarters before and including 2007Q1, and one after that. pr eotdi is the average value of OTD
mortgages to total mortgages during quarters 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. μi denotes bank fixed effects;
X stands for a set of control variables. premortgage is the average ratio of mortgage assets to total assets for
2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. logta measures the log of total assets; cil/ta is the ratio of commercial and in-
dustrial loans to total assets; liquid is the bank’s liquid assets to total assets ratio; absgap is the absolute value of
one-year maturity gap as a fraction of total assets. Adjusted R-squared and number of observations are provided
in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.

on a bank’s mortgage default rates during the post-disruption quarters. In the


chargeoff regression model (Model 1), we find a positive and significant co-
efficient of 0.0420 on a f ter ∗ pr eotd. In Model 2, we repeat the analysis
with non-performing mortgages as the measure of loan quality and again find
a positive and significant coefficient on the interaction term. These effects are
economically large as well. For example, based on the estimates of Model 2, a
one-standard-deviation increase in pr eotd results in an increase of about 11%
in the mortgage default rate as compared with the unconditional sample mean.
We repeat our analysis after excluding large banks from the sample and obtain
similar results.11
In our next test, we model mortgage defaults as a function of the extent
of OTD loans that a bank is stuck with. For every bank in the sample, we
create a measure of stuck loans in the following manner. We first compute
the quarterly average of OTD loans originated during the pre-crisis quarters;
i.e., during the quarters 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. From this, we subtract
the quarterly average of loans sold during the post-crisis periods; i.e., during

11 In an unreported robustness exercise, we drop the first two quarters after the beginning of the crisis from our
sample. We do so to allow more time for the mortgages to default after the beginning of the crisis. Our results
become slightly stronger for this specification.

1895
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

Table 4
Mortgage default and inability to sell
All Banks Excludes Large Banks
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Chargeoffs NPA Chargeoffs NPA

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Dependent Var: Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat
after 0.0131 (2.18) 0.3113 (2.81) 0.0148 (2.25) 0.2791 (2.35)
after*stuck 0.0922 (3.03) 1.4342 (3.64) 0.0940 (3.02) 1.2756 (3.39)
after*premortgage 0.0000 (0.00) 0.5888 (1.11) −0.0110 (−0.35) 0.3892 (0.75)
logta 0.1004 (4.64) 0.3684 (0.85) 0.0855 (3.02) 0.8078 (1.67)
cil/ta 0.1964 (1.62) 2.3276 (1.25) 0.1675 (1.34) 2.0930 (1.07)
liquid 0.0633 (1.05) 1.1788 (0.83) 0.1047 (1.60) −0.2045 (−0.19)
absgap −0.0603 (−1.43) −3.1394 (−3.79) −0.0690 (−1.54) −3.0421 (−3.59)

R2 0.3818 0.7330 0.3635 0.7162


N 5397 5397 4977 4977

This table provides regression results for the following fixed-effect model:
k=K
X
de f aultit = μi + β1 a f tert + β2 a f tert ∗ stucki + β X + it .
k=1
The dependent variable, de f aultit , is measured by either the mortgage chargeoffs or the non-performing mort-
gages of bank i during quarter t . a f tert is a dummy variable that is set to zero for quarters before and including
2007Q1, and one after that. stucki measures the difference between loans originated before 2007Q1 and loans
sold after this quarter. μi denotes bank fixed effects; X stands for a set of control variables. premortgage is the
average ratio of mortgage assets to total assets for 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. logta measures the log of
total assets; cil/ta is the ratio of commercial and industrial loans to total assets; liquid is the bank’s liquid assets
to total assets ratio; absgap is the absolute value of one-year maturity gap as a fraction of total assets. Adjusted
R-squared and number of observations are provided in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the
bank level.

2007Q2 to 2008Q1. We scale the difference by the bank’s average mortgage


assets during the pre-crisis quarters. This variable refines the earlier pr eotd
measure by subtracting the extent of loans that a bank could actually sell in
the post-disruption period. This variable allows us to more directly analyze
the effect of loans that a bank had originated to distribute but was unable to
distribute due to the drop in liquidity in the secondary market.12
We re-estimate the de f ault regression model by replacing pr eotd with
stuck. Results are presented in Table 4. We find a large positive coefficient
on the interaction term pr eotd ∗ stuck in Model 1. In unreported tests, we run
a horse race between a f ter ∗ pr eotd and a f ter ∗ stuck and find that the effect
of OTD loans on mortgage chargeoffs mainly comes from the variation in the
stuck variable. Similar results hold for mortgage default rate using NPA as the
dependent variable (see Model 2). Models 3 and 4 show that our results are
robust to the exclusion of large banks. In a nutshell, these results provide more
direct evidence that banks that were stuck with OTD loans experienced larger
mortgage defaults in the post-disruption period.

12 It is worth pointing out that this measure is not a perfect proxy for stuck loans because it does not directly match
loan origination with selling at the loan-by-loan level. However, in the absence of detailed loan-level data, it is a
reasonable proxy for the cross-sectional dispersion of stuck loans at the bank level.

1896
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

Overall, we show that OTD loans were of inferior quality because banks that
were stuck with these loans in the post-disruption period had disproportion-
ately higher chargeoffs and borrower defaults. While these results are consis-
tent with the hypothesis of dilution in screening standards of high-OTD banks,
there are two important alternative explanations: (a) Do high-OTD banks ex-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


perience higher default rates because of observable differences in their borrow-
ers’ characteristics? and (b) Do these banks make riskier loans because they
have a lower cost of capital (e.g., see Pennacchi 1988)? Our key challenge is
to establish a causal link from OTD lending to mortgage default rate that is not
explained away by these differences. Since the pullback in liquidity happened
at the same time for all banks, we need to be especially careful in ruling out
the effect of macroeconomic factors from the screening effect of pr eotd on
mortgage defaults. We extend our study in two directions to address these con-
cerns. We first use a series of matched sample tests using detailed loan-level
data to compare banks that made loans to observationally equivalent borrow-
ers before the onset of the crisis. The key idea behind these tests is to compare
borrowers that look similar on the hard information dimension so that we can
attribute higher default rates of high-OTD banks to their lower underwriting
standards in a clear manner. In our second set of tests, we exploit the variation
in mortgage default rates within the set of high-OTD banks. In particular, we
analyze the effect of banks’ liability structure on the quality of OTD loans to
isolate the effect of screening standards. These tests also help us understand
the key driving forces behind the origination of poor-quality OTD loans.

3. Matched sample analysis


We use the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) database to obtain infor-
mation on the characteristics of mortgages made by commercial banks during
2006. HMDA was enacted by Congress in 1975 to improve disclosure and pro-
mote fairness in the mortgage lending market. The HMDA database is a com-
prehensive source of loan-level data on mortgages made by commercial banks,
credit unions, and savings institutions. The database provides detailed infor-
mation on the property’s location, borrower’s income, and loan amount along
with a host of borrower and geographical characteristics on a loan-by-loan ba-
sis. We match bank-level call report data with loan-level HMDA data using
the FDIC certificate number (call report data item RSSD 9050), FRS identi-
fication number (RSSD 9001), and OCC charter number (RSSD 9055) of the
commercial banks. With the matched sample of banks and individual loans, we
proceed in four steps to rule out several possible alternative hypotheses.

3.1 Matching based on observable borrower characteristics


Are our results completely driven by differences in observable borrower and
loan characteristics of high- and low-OTD banks? We construct a matched
sample of high- and low-OTD banks that are similar on key observable

1897
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

dimensions of credit risk to rule out this hypothesis. We divide sample banks
into two groups (above and below median) based on their involvement in the
OTD market prior to the disruption (i.e., pr eotd variable). Our goal is to match
every high-OTD bank with a low-OTD bank that has made mortgages in a sim-
ilar geographical area to observationally similar borrowers.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


We first match on the geographical location of properties to control for the
effect of changes in house prices for loans made by high- and low-OTD banks.
We compute the fraction of loans issued by a given bank in every state and then
take the state with the highest fraction as the bank’s main state. This method
allows us to match on the location of property rather than on the state of incor-
poration in case they are different. There can be considerable variation in hous-
ing returns within a state or even within a metropolitan statistical area (MSA)
(e.g., see Goetzmann and Spiegel 1997). Our choice of state-level matching
is driven purely by empirical data limitations. As we show later, our matched
sample is well balanced along several important characteristics, such as the
median household income of the neighborhood, that are shown to explain the
within-MSA variation in house prices. In unreported robustness tests, we carry
out a matched sample analysis based on matching within the MSA and find
similar results. Since our sample size drops considerably as we narrow the ge-
ographical unit of matching, all results in the article are based on state-level
matching.
We obtain two key measures of the borrower’s credit quality from the HMDA
dataset: (1) loan-to-income ratio; and (2) borrower’s annual income. We com-
pute the average income and the average loan-to-income ratio of all loans made
by a bank during 2006 on a bank-by-bank basis. Our matching procedure pro-
ceeds as follows. We take a high-OTD bank (i.e., above-median pr eotd bank)
and consider all low-OTD banks in the same state as potential matching banks.
We break banks into three size groups based on their total assets: (1) below
$100 million; (2) between $100 million and $1 billion; and (3) between $1
billion and $10 billion. We do not include banks with asset size more than $10
billion in this analysis to ensure that our results are not contaminated by very
large banks operating across multiple markets.13 From the set of all low-OTD
banks in the same state, we consider banks in the same size group as the high-
OTD bank’s size group. We further limit this subset to banks that are within
50% of the high-OTD bank in terms of average income and average loan-to-
income ratio of their borrowers.14 From this subset, we take the bank with the
closest average loan-to-income ratio as the matched bank. We match without
replacement to find unique matching banks.
Our goal is to find pairs of banks that have made mortgages to observa-
tionally equivalent borrowers, but with varying intensity of OTD loans. We

13 We have estimated the model without this restriction, and all results remain similar.

14 Similar results hold if we narrow this band to 25%.

1898
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

have conducted several alternative matching criteria by changing the cutoffs


for bank size, borrower’s income, and loan-to-income ratio. Our results are ro-
bust. To save space, we provide estimation results for the base model only. Due
to the strict matching criteria, our sample size drops for this study. We are able
to match 180 high-OTD banks using this methodology.15

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Given the matching criteria, this sample is dominated by regional banks.
The average asset size of banks in this matched sample is $1.71 billion for
the high-OTD banks and $1.65 billion for the low-OTD banks. In Figure 5,
we plot the distribution of loan-to-income ratio and borrower’s annual income
across high- and low-OTD banks in the matched sample. Not surprisingly, the
two distributions are almost identical. In unreported tests, we find that these
two groups are well balanced along several geographical dimensions such as
neighborhood median income and the population of the census tract. Thus our
banks are matched along the socioeconomic distance as well, which provides
further confidence in the comparability of house price changes across these two
groups (see Goetzmann and Spiegel 1997). In unreported analysis, we compare
several other characteristics across the two groups and analyze them using the
Kolmogorov-Smirnov test for the equality of distribution. We find that these
two groups are statistically indistinguishable in terms of the following charac-
teristics: borrower’s income, loan-to-income ratio, loan amount, loan security,
and neighborhood income.
We conduct our tests on the matched sample and report the bank fixed-effect
estimation results in Table 5. Since our results remain similar for both measures
of mortgage default, to save space we report results based on non-performing
assets only. We find a positive and significant coefficient of 0.89–0.90 on the
interaction term a f ter ∗ pr eotd in Models 1 and 3. Thus, even after condition-
ing our sample to banks that are comparable along several risk characteristics
and property locations, banks that engaged in a higher fraction of OTD lending
experienced higher default rates on their mortgage portfolios in quarters just
after the onset of the crisis. Models 2 and 4 of the table use a f ter ∗ stuck as
the key right-hand-side variable to assess the impact of OTD lending on mort-
gage default rates for banks that are more likely to be stuck with these loans.
We find strong results. Banks that originated a significant amount of mortgage
loans with an intention to sell them to third parties, but could not offload them
in the secondary market, suffered much higher mortgage default rates.
In economic terms, our estimation shows that banks with one-standard-
deviation-higher OTD lending have a mortgage default rate that is about 0.45%
higher. This represents a default rate that is 32% higher than the unconditional
sample median of this variable. The economic magnitude of the matched sam-
ple results are stronger than the base case specification presented in Table 3.

15 Since we impose a restriction of balanced panel in our study, in regressions we lose few observation due to the
non-availability of other data items for all seven quarters. Our results remain robust to the inclusion of these
observations in the sample.

1899
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020

Figure 5
Distribution of key characteristics of high- and low-OTD banks after matching
The plots give the kernel density functions of the key characteristics of the high- and low-OTD banks after
matching. More details on the matching are provided in the article. The first plot is for the loan-to-income ratios;
the second plot is for the borrowers’ annual income.

The coefficient on a f ter ∗ pr eotd is almost twice as much as the base case
that uses all bank-quarter observations. However, we cannot compare these
two estimates directly because they are estimated on different samples.

1900
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

Table 5
Matched sample analysis: Base case
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
NPA NPA NPA NPA
Dependent Var: Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


after 0.5657 (6.28) 0.5422 (6.45) 0.4044 (2.15) 0.3649 (1.97)
after*preotd 0.8997 (2.83) 0.9043 (2.94)
after*stuck 2.3613 (3.89) 2.3898 (4.19)
after*premortgage 0.3076 (0.38) 0.2376 (0.31)
logta 0.6920 (0.72) 0.9455 (1.02)
cil/ta 1.9596 (0.66) 2.0078 (0.69)
absgap −5.6376 (−3.78) −5.4404 (−3.74)
liquid 0.5862 (0.18) −0.0657 (−0.02)

R2 0.7039 0.7113 0.7136 0.7212


N 2289 2289 2289 2289

This table reports the estimation results of fixed-effect regressions on a matched sample of high- and low-OTD
banks. Banks are matched on geographical location of their mortgage portfolios, the borrowers’ loan-to-income
ratio, the borrowers’ annual income, and the bank’s size. The dependent variable is the non-performing mortgage
loans of banks in a given quarter. The definitions of variables and details of the model estimation are provided in
the article. Adjusted R-squared and number of observations are provided in the bottom rows. All standard errors
are clustered at the bank level.

Overall, the analysis of this section shows that the variation generated by the
OTD model of lending is unlikely to be explained away by differences in bor-
rower’s credit risk, property location, bank size, or other bank characteristics.

3.2 Matching based on interest rates


Our results suggest that OTD mortgages performed much worse even after
conditioning on observable borrower characteristics. This leads to two pos-
sibilities: (1) these loans were different on unobservable dimensions and the
originating banks properly priced these unobservable factors to account for
the higher risk; or (2) the originating banks didn’t expend enough resources
in screening these borrowers because the loans would be subsequently sold to
third parties. Although both of these hypotheses are consistent with the view
that OTD loans were riskier, under the first possibility the bank is properly
screening these loans and pricing them accordingly.
We conduct a specific matched sample analysis to separate these two hy-
potheses. By definition, it is impossible for us to directly incorporate the unob-
servable dimensions of borrowers’ risk in our analysis. However, if banks are
expending resources in screening the high-risk OTD loans, then this fact must
be reflected in the loan pricing. We exploit this idea in the following test.
In addition to property location and borrower’s loan-to-income ratio, we
now also match on the interest rates charged by the banks at the time of the
loan origination. The HMDA database reports loan spreads for high-risk bor-
rowers only. The reporting requirement stipulates that banks should report loan
spreads on all first-security loans with a spread of above 3% and all junior se-
curity loans with a spread of above 5%. Thus, these loans generally fall in the

1901
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

subprime category. Though we are unable to match on loan spreads for the en-
tire mortgage portfolio, it is this subset that is more meaningful in terms of our
economic exercise. We compute the average loan spread on a bank-by-bank
basis and then match banks based on these averages.
For every high-OTD bank, we first find a set of low-OTD banks that meet

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


the following criteria: (1) they primarily operate in the same state as the high-
OTD bank; (2) they are in the same size group; (3) they are within 50% of the
average loan-to-income ratio of the high-OTD bank; and (4) they are within
50% of the average loan spread of the high-OTD bank. From this set, we select
the low-OTD bank with the closest loan spread as the matched bank.
The resulting matched sample comprises a set of high- and low-OTD banks
that have made mortgages to observationally equivalent borrowers in similar
geographical areas at similar rates. We compare the distribution of key bor-
rower characteristics for this matched sample as well. As expected, we find
that the high- and low-OTD banks in this sample have borrowers with simi-
lar loan-to-income ratio, income, loan security, and neighborhood income. We
plot the distribution of loan-to-income ratio and the borrowers’ income across
these groups in Figure 5. The two distributions fall mostly in the common
support zone. In unreported analysis, we compare these characteristics with
formal statistical tests. Based on the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test for equality of
distribution, we find that these two groups are statistically indistinguishable
from each other on each of these dimensions. The extent of mortgage loans as
a fraction of total assets made by these banks in the pre-disruption period is
also statistically indistinguishable.
By construction, high- and low-OTD banks in this sample differ in the ex-
tent of OTD loans made during the pre-disruption period. Thus, this sample
exploits the variation along the OTD dimension, keeping several observable
characteristics and the priced component of unobservable characteristics con-
stant. If banks screened the OTD loans and incorporated the effect of privately
acquired information into the pricing of these loans, then we should not expect
to see any difference in the performance of high- and low-OTD mortgages in
this subsample. If, in contrast, riskier loans were made without properly incor-
porating the effect of unobservable risk in loan pricing, then we are likely to
see differences in the performance of these loans even in this subsample.
This test also allows us to overcome some of the data limitations of the
HMDA dataset. Although the HMDA database is one of the most compre-
hensive loan-level data sources available for mortgage loans, it omits some
relevant information about the borrower’s credit risk, such as FICO scores.
Our matching exercise in the earlier section is based on the assumption that
characteristics such as loan-to-income ratio, borrower’s income, neighborhood
income, and property location capture a significant part of the default risk of
loan applicants. The matched sample exercise of this section allows us to con-
trol for any omitted variables, such as FICO scores that may be relevant for
the banks’ credit decision. Information on FICO score or any other variables

1902
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

Table 6
Matched sample analysis: Average loan spread charged
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
NPA NPA NPA NPA
Dependent Var: Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


after 0.5060 (5.58) 0.4911 (5.79) 0.2791 (1.53) 0.2505 (1.40)
after*preotd 0.6557 (2.28) 0.6880 (2.44)
after*stuck 1.7369 (3.13) 1.8194 (3.33)
after*premortgage 0.4686 (0.64) 0.4364 (0.60)
logta 0.4861 (0.86) 0.6906 (1.22)
cil/ta 0.3309 (0.12) 0.3722 (0.13)
absgap −4.5193 (−3.31) −4.5168 (−3.29)
liquid −2.1793 (−1.35) −2.3290 (−1.46)

R2 0.7049 0.7098 0.7118 0.7170


N 2205 2205 2205 2205

This table reports the estimation results of fixed-effect regressions on a matched sample of high- and low-OTD
banks. Banks are matched on geographical location of their mortgage portfolios, bank size, the borrowers’ loan-
to-income ratio, and the average rate spread on the subprime loan portfolio of the bank. The dependent variable
is the non-performing mortgage loans of the banks in a given quarter. The definition of variables and details of
the model estimation are provided in the article. Adjusted R-squared and number of observations are provided
in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.

used in the process of lending should ultimately be reflected in the rate that
banks charge their borrowers. Thus, by exploiting the variation along the OTD
dimension, while keeping the interest rates similar, we are able to more pre-
cisely estimate the effect of securitization on screening.
Table 6 shows the results. In Models 1 and 2, we estimate the effect of
pr eotd and stuck variables on mortgage default rates without controlling for
other bank characteristics. Models 3 and 4 include control variables as well.
We find strong evidence that banks that originated a large volume of mort-
gages that were intended to be sold in the OTD market experienced larger
mortgage default on their portfolios in quarters immediately following the cri-
sis. The effect is stronger for banks that were unable to sell these loans. A
one-standard-deviation increase in OTD lending in the pre-crisis period results
in an increase of 0.38% in the mortgage default rate after the crisis. This in-
crease is approximately 26% of the matched sample’s median mortgage default
rate.
Even for banks that charged similar rates to their borrowers and made most
of their loans in the same geographical area, the performance of high-OTD
banks is significantly worse in the post-disruption period. Conditional on inter-
est rates, there should be no relationship between OTD lending and post-crisis
default rates if these two groups of loans were made with equal screening ef-
forts. However, if high-OTD loans were granted without proper screening on
unobservable dimensions, then we are likely to find higher default rates for
high-OTD banks even within this sample. The evidence of this section sug-
gests that OTD loans were made without proper screening on unobservable
dimensions.

1903
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

3.3 Other tests


To complement the results discussed in the previous section, we conduct an
additional matched sample test in which we match banks based on the fraction
of high-risk loans made during 2006. We compute the fraction of subprime
loans made by a bank by computing the ratio of high-spread loans to total

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


loans based on the HMDA dataset. High-spread loans are defined as first-lien
loans with a rate spread of more than 3% or second-lien loans with a rate
spread of more than 5%. Our matching exercise is the same as in the previous
section, except that now we ensure that the fraction of subprime loans (i.e.,
high-interest-rate loans) made by these banks are similar. In unreported results,
we find that OTD lending has a strong effect on mortgage default rate even in
this subsample. The estimated economic magnitudes are similar to the interest-
rate-based matched sample results of the previous section.
In the preceding analyses, we create carefully matched pairs of high- and
low-OTD banks that have similar characteristics. Depending on the matching
criteria, we obtain different samples of high- and low-OTD banks, and we show
that our key results remain similar across these subsamples. A limitation of this
approach is that we conduct our experiments with smaller samples due to the
strict matching requirements. Therefore, as a complement to these tests, we use
regression methods to control for differences in borrowers’ risk characteristics.
We estimate the following model:
m=M
X
defaultit = μi + β1 aftert + β2 aftert ∗ pr eotdi + βm aftert ∗ riskim
m=1
k=K
X
+ βk X ikt + it .
k=1

riski represents a vector of borrowers’ default risk for bank i. We interact these
measures with a f ter to separate out the effect of borrower risk characteristics
on default rates after the crisis from the bank’s OTD lending. We use several
measures of default risk, such as loan-to-income ratio, annual income, average
interest rate charged by the bank, fraction of subprime loans in a bank’s port-
folio, and the fraction of low-documentation loans in its portfolio. Our results
remain robust to this alternative specification. To save space, we do not present
these results in the article.

3.4 Cost of capital channel


An important benefit of the OTD model is that it allows the selling bank to
lower its cost of capital. Pennacchi (1988) shows that banks can lower their
cost of capital by transferring credit risk through loan sales. In a competitive
deposits market, loan sales can lower the bank’s cost of capital by allowing
it to save on regulatory capital and required reserves (see also Gorton and
Pennacchi 1995). If high-OTD banks have a lower cost of capital, then they

1904
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

can make loans to relatively higher-credit-risk borrowers since some of these


borrowers present positive NPV projects only to the high-OTD banks. There-
fore, the ex post performance of the higher OTD banks’ mortgage portfolio is
likely to be worse in bad economic times due to the presence of these marginal
borrowers.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Are our results simply driven by the lower cost of capital of high-OTD
banks? To rule out this alternative hypothesis, we compare the performance
of smaller banks having large OTD portfolios with that of larger banks having
little to no involvement in the OTD model of lending. Our assumption is that
it is unlikely that a small bank, even after engaging in the OTD model of lend-
ing, has a lower cost of capital than a bank that is several times bigger. Several
empirical studies find a negative link between firm size and its cost of capital.
Thus, this test allows us to compare the performance of OTD loans issued by
banks with a higher cost of capital with the performance of non-OTD banks
with a relatively lower cost of capital.
We compute the bank’s average assets during the pre-disruption quarters
(i.e., 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1) and classify them into the small bank
group if their assets are less than $1 billion. From this set, we obtain banks with
higher-than-median levels of OTD lending during the pre-disruption quarters.
For every small bank, we consider all large banks (assets greater than $10
billion) in the below-median OTD group that have made the largest fraction
of mortgages in the same state as the small bank. We require the large bank’s
borrowers’ average income to fall within 50% of the small bank’s borrowers.
From the resulting set, we select the large bank with a loan-to-income ratio
closest to that of the matched bank. Given the strict nature of matching, our
sample drops considerably for this analysis. We are able to obtain a match for
83 small banks by this method. The average asset size of high-OTD banks in
this sample is $600 million, whereas the low-OTD banks have an average asset
size of about $8.76 billion.
We re-estimate our models for this subsample and present the results in
Table 7. Our results remain strong. The high-OTD small banks originated sig-
nificantly lower-quality mortgages than the low-OTD large banks. The differ-
ential effect of OTD loans, therefore, is unlikely to be explained away by the
lower cost of capital of high-OTD banks.

3.5 Shrinkage in loan spreads


In this section, we provide more direct evidence in support of the dilution
in screening standards based on an analysis of the dispersion in loan spreads
charged by high- and low-OTD banks. To motivate the empirical test, con-
sider a setting in which two originating banks are faced with similar pools of
borrowers based on observable characteristics. Bank S screens the applicants,
evaluates their true creditworthiness based on privately observed signals, and
grants loans at a fair price. Bank NS does not screen its borrowers and offers
them a standard rate conditional on observable signals. In this model, the S

1905
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

Table 7
Matched sample analysis: Small to big
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
NPA NPA NPA NPA
Dependent Var: Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


after 0.4577 (4.18) 0.4377 (4.36) −0.0232 (−0.11) −0.0922 (−0.44)
after*preotd 0.8384 (2.33) 0.8665 (2.38)
after*stuck 2.0376 (2.60) 2.2099 (2.81)
after*premortgage 1.4795 (1.43) 1.4727 (1.40)
logta 2.3183 (1.77) 2.7952 (2.28)
cil/ta 4.3085 (0.80) 3.2424 (0.59)
absgap −4.7469 (−2.25) −4.6843 (−2.29)
liquid 3.4007 (0.74) 3.1728 (0.71)

R2 0.6966 0.7046 0.7117 0.7230


N 1148 1148 1148 1148

This table reports the estimation results of fixed-effect regressions on a matched sample of high- and low-OTD
banks. We match small banks with large OTD lending with large banks with little to no OTD lending. The
dependent variable is the non-performing mortgage loans of the banks in a given quarter. The definitions of
variables and details of the model estimation are provided in the article. Adjusted R-squared and number of
observations are provided in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.

bank discriminates its borrowers significantly more than the NS bank for the
same set of observable characteristics of the borrowers. Therefore, loan rates
charged by the S bank will have a wider distribution than the loan rates charged
by the NS bank for observationally equivalent borrowers. Thus, if the high-
OTD banks are of the NS type, then we expect to observe tighter distribution
of loan rates for these banks after parsing out the effect of observable signals.
This test is in line with the arguments developed more formally in Rajan, Seru,
and Vig (2009), who argue that the default prediction models fail in systematic
ways as the reliance on hard information in loan-approval decisions increases.
Based on this idea, we compare the distribution of loan spreads charged to
borrowers across high- and low-OTD banks. We first obtain all loan-level ob-
servation from the HMDA data with non-missing observation on loan spreads.
As discussed earlier, these data are reported for very high-risk borrowers only;
i.e., for the subset for which the effect of lax screening is potentially higher.
We first estimate the following model of loan spread to parse out the effect of
observable characteristics:
rateib = α + β X ib + ib .
rateib is the log percentage spread (over comparable maturity treasury secu-
rity) on mortgage to borrower i by bank b. X ib is a set of borrower, loan, and
bank characteristics that are observable and likely to affect the loan rate. We
include the following borrower characteristics in the model: log of borrower’s
annual income, log of loan amount, loan-to-income ratio, log of neighborhood
median family income reported by HMDA, percentage minority population in
the neighborhood, whether the loan is secured by a first lien or not, whether the
property is occupied by the owner or not, purpose of the loan (home purchase,

1906
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

Table 8
Shrinkage in loan spread
Panel A: All Banks Panel B: Matched Sample
High OTD Low OTD Shrinkage High OTD Low OTD Shrinkage
Standard Deviation 0.2236 0.2621 0.0385 0.2056 0.2627 0.0571

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


P75-P25 0.3144 0.3559 0.0415 0.2731 0.3669 0.0938
P90-P10 0.5697 0.6767 0.1070 0.5172 0.6883 0.1711
Bartlett’s p-value 0.0001 0.0001
Levene’s p-value 0.0001 0.0001

This table provides the dispersion in loan spread across high- (above-median) and low- (below-median) OTD
banks. Panel A is for all banks, and Panel B for the matched sample. We provide three measures of dispersion
in log loan spreads: standard deviation, the difference between the 75th and 25th percentiles, and the difference
between the 90th and 10th percentiles. Shrinkage measures the difference in dispersion across the high- and
low-OTD banks. Bartlett’s and Levene’s p-values are for the null hypothesis that the variance of loan spreads for
the high-OTD group equals the variance of loan spreads for the low-OTD group.

improvement, or refinancing), loan type (conventional or Federal Housing Ad-


ministration (FHA)-insured loan), indicator for the state of the property, and
the applicant’s sex and race. This is a comprehensive set of characteristics
aimed at capturing the borrowers’ default risk, demographics, and other cor-
related variables. In addition to these factors, we also include the bank’s asset
size (log of assets), liquidity ratio, maturity gap, CIL loans to total asset ratio,
and the ratio of mortgage loans to total assets. These variables are included to
control for bank-specific effects in pricing such as the bank’s cost of capital
and relative advantage in making mortgage loans.16
We are interested in the dispersion of the residual of this regression; i.e.,
ib . Our hypothesis is that the high-OTD banks did not incur resources in dis-
criminating across borrowers with similar observable quality but with different
unobservable signals. ib captures the effect of such unobservable factors. We
compute three measures of dispersion in ib : (1) standard deviation; (2) dif-
ference between the 75th and 25th percentiles; and (3) difference between the
90th and 10th percentiles. Table 8 reports the results. Panel A presents results
for all banks, whereas Panel B is for the matched sample used in subsection
3.1. We find a consistent pattern of shrinkage in loan spreads for the high-OTD
banks. The standard deviation of loan rates issued by the high- (above-median)
OTD banks is about 17–28% lower than the low- (below-median) OTD banks.
We observe similar patterns for other two measures of dispersion as well. We
conduct Bartlett’s test for the equality of variance of the two distributions and
strongly reject the null hypothesis of equal variance for the two groups. Lev-
ene’s test statistics for the equality of variance produce similar results. The
Kolmogorov-Smirnov test statistic strongly rejects the equality of the two dis-
tributions as well.

16 We have experimented with several other reasonable specifications and obtained similar results. We report results
based on one of the most comprehensive models to isolate the effect of observable information on loan spreads.

1907
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

Overall, we show that the low-OTD banks offered loans at more discrim-
inating terms for the same observable characteristics as compared with the
high-OTD banks. This finding is consistent with the assertion that the high-
OTD banks did not expend as much resources in screening their borrowers as
their low-OTD counterparts.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


4. Capital and Liability Structure
We have so far established a link between OTD lending and the banks’ screen-
ing incentives. Going forward, it is important to understand the characteristics
of banks that engaged in such behavior. We do so by analyzing the effect of a
bank’s liability structure on the quality of OTD loans that it originated in the
pre-disruption period. These tests serve two purposes. First, they allow us to
sharpen our basic test that relates OTD lending to screening incentives. Sec-
ond, they provide useful guidance for policy reforms that are aimed at deterring
such behavior in the future.

4.1 Effect of capital constraints


As discussed earlier, the OTD model of lending has several advantages. By
de-linking the origination of loans from their funding, banks can capitalize
on their comparative advantage in loan origination without holding a large
capital base. The benefit can be especially high for banks with a lower cap-
ital base because these banks are more likely to reject the loan application of
a potentially creditworthy borrower due to regulatory capital constraints. The
OTD model of lending allows these capital-constrained banks to provide credit
to such marginal creditworthy borrowers. Thus, the securitized loans of such
capital-constrained banks are likely to be of better quality than the securitized
loans of unconstrained banks that face a similar set of borrowers.
In contrast, capital-constrained banks have lower screening and monitoring
incentives (see Thakor 1996; Holmstrom and Tirole 1997) due to the well-
known risk-shifting problem (Jensen and Meckling 1976). If banks are using
the OTD market to create riskier loans by diluting their screening standards,
then capital-constrained banks are predicted to have higher incentives to make
inferior loans. Thus, we have sharply different predictions on the effect of cap-
ital constraints on the extent of mortgage defaults by high pr eotd banks: one
consistent with the sound economic motivation to economize on regulatory
capital, and the other consistent with diluted screening incentives. We estimate
the following triple-differencing model to test this prediction:
defaultit = μi + β1 aftert + β2 aftert ∗ preotdi + β2 aftert ∗ capi
k=K
X
+ β3 aftert ∗ preotdi ∗ capi + β X + it .
k=1

The dependent variable, de f aultit , measures the mortgage default rate of bank
i in quarter t. capi measures the tier-one capital ratio of bank i during the

1908
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

Table 9
The effect of bank capital
All Banks Excludes Large Banks
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
NPA NPA NPA NPA

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Dependent Var: Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat
after 0.2390 (1.06) −0.6064 (−2.16) 0.1240 (0.51) −0.7314 (−2.43)
after*cap 0.8111 (0.45) 0.9272 (0.55) 1.4960 (0.76) 1.8426 (1.01)
after*preotd*cap −5.4985 (−2.05) −5.2733 (−2.01) −5.1978 (−1.89) −5.2544 (−1.93)
after*preotd 1.1495 (2.49) 1.0360 (2.31) 1.0716 (2.25) 1.0056 (2.16)
after*premortgage 0.6313 (1.17) 0.8177 (1.56) 0.4066 (0.78) 0.6109 (1.16)
logta 0.2335 (0.53) 0.3191 (0.75) 0.7031 (1.45) 0.7281 (1.48)
cil/ta 2.5588 (1.34) 2.8332 (1.45) 2.2419 (1.12) 2.5009 (1.22)
liquid 1.3795 (0.91) 1.3492 (0.95) −0.1292 (−0.12) −0.1240 (−0.11)
absgap −3.2334 (−3.81) −3.0484 (−3.69) −3.1012 (−3.61) −3.0050 (−3.51)
after*li 0.2714 (2.64) 0.2827 (2.63)
after*highrate 1.9064 (3.85) 1.6838 (3.67)
after*noincome 0.6671 (2.42) 0.5810 (1.87)

R2 0.7303 0.7340 0.7140 0.7160


N 5397 5327 4977 4907

This table provides the regression results of the following fixed-effect model:
defaultit = μi + β1 aftert + β2 aftert ∗ preotdi + β2 aftert ∗ capi
k=K
X
+ β3 aftert ∗ preotdi ∗ capi + β X + it .
k=1
The dependent variable, de f aultit , is measured as the ratio of non-performing mortgages to the outstanding
mortgage loans of bank i during quarter t. a f tert is a dummy variable that is set to zero for quarters before and
including 2007Q1, and one after that. pr eotdi is the average value of OTD mortgages to total mortgages during
quarters 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1; capi is bank i ’s average tier-one capital ratio during quarters 2006Q3,
2006Q4, and 2007Q1; μi denotes bank fixed effects; X stands for a set of control variables. premortgage is the
average ratio of mortgage assets to total assets for 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. logta measures the log of total
assets; cil/ta is the ratio of commercial and industrial loans to total assets; liquid is the bank’s liquid assets to
total assets ratio; absgap is the absolute value of one-year maturity gap as a fraction of total assets. li measures
the average loan-to-income ratio of all loans issued by the bank in 2006. highrate measures the fraction of
high-interest-rate loans originated by the bank, and noincome measures the fraction of loans without income
documentation originated by the bank in 2006. Adjusted R-squared and number of observations are provided in
the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.

pre-disruption quarters. We take the average value of this ratio for the pre-
disruption quarters (2006Q3 to 2007Q1) to capture the effect of the capital
ratio at the time these loans were made. Table 9 provides the estimation results.
Consistent with our earlier analysis, we present results for both the “All Bank”
sample and the “Excluding Large Banks” subsample. In Models 1 and 3, we
estimate the regression model with bank-level control variables only. Models
2 and 4 control for borrower characteristics based on the HMDA dataset for
2006.
It is important to note that banks choose their capital ratios endogenously.
This raises a potential concern for our identification strategy in this section. For
example, consider a bank CEO who prefers higher risk for some unobserved
reasons. A bank with such a CEO is likely to keep lower capital and at the
same time originate riskier loans in the OTD market. Our triple-difference tests

1909
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

exploit variations within the set of high-OTD banks. Said differently, the coef-
ficient on the triple-interaction term measures the incremental effect of capital
constraints, holding fixed the level of OTD loans. The unconditional effect of
capital constraint is captured by the double-interaction term a f ter ∗ cap. The
test design, therefore, minimizes the endogeneity concerns to a large extent.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


In addition, Models 2 and 4 control for borrowers’ risk characteristics, which
further alleviates the concern regarding the endogeneity of bank capital.
We find a positive and significant coefficient on a f ter ∗ pr eotd in all spec-
ifications, confirming our earlier results that banks with higher-OTD loans in
the pre-crisis period experienced larger defaults on their mortgage portfolios
in the post-crisis quarters. The coefficient on a f ter ∗ cap is positive but in-
significant. The coefficient on the triple-interaction term; i.e., the coefficient
of interest, is negative and statistically significant. Thus, the effect of OTD
lending on mortgage default rate weakens for banks with a higher capital base.
In other words, the relationship between OTD lending and mortgage default
rate is predominantly concentrated among banks with lower capital. A one-
standard-deviation decrease in the capital ratio translates into 0.18% higher
defaults, which is about 13% of the sample median of mortgage default rates.
This result shows that banks used the OTD channel mainly to originate poor-
quality loans rather than to save on regulatory capital. The result, therefore, is
consistent with the dilution in screening standards of the high-OTD banks.

4.2 Effect of demand deposits


We study the effect of demand deposits on the quality of OTD loans in order to
further understand the role of funding structure on the banks’ lending behav-
ior. We focus on demand deposits because their presence is one of the defining
features of commercial banks (see Diamond and Dybvig 1983). There are two
economic forces leading to opposite predictions about the role of demand de-
posits on a bank’s lending behavior. While the presence of subsidized deposit
insurance might encourage banks with a large demand deposit base to engage
in imprudent risk-taking behavior, the fragility induced by demand deposits
can also act as a disciplining device. The threat of large-scale inefficient with-
drawal by the depositors can exert an ex ante pressure on the bank managers’
risk-taking behavior. Calomoris and Kahn (1991) and Flannery (1994) provide
theoretical arguments that demand deposits can control imprudent risk-taking
activities of a bank. Diamond and Rajan (2001) show that the demand deposits
can act as a disciplining device by committing the banker to avoid undesirable
risky behavior. The franchise value associated with a large deposit base might
limit a bank’s risk-taking behavior as well.
We examine the role of demand deposit on risk-taking through the OTD
model of lending using the same empirical methodology that we use for the
test involving the effect of capital ratios. We estimate a triple-differencing
model and provide results in Table 10. We measure the extent of dependence

1910
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

Table 10
The effect of demand deposits
All Banks Excludes Large Banks
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
NPA NPA NPA NPA

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Dependent Var: Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat
after 0.5045 (3.66) −0.2957 (−1.38) 0.4479 (3.00) −0.3404 (−1.52)
after*dd −1.6465 (−2.43) −1.6697 (−2.44) −1.3884 (−1.98) −1.4100 (−2.02)
after*preotd*dd −3.9949 (−2.34) −3.7627 (−2.25) −3.4250 (−2.09) −3.2896 (−2.04)
after*preotd 0.9364 (2.79) 0.8260 (2.58) 0.8294 (2.52) 0.7423 (2.32)
after*premortgage 0.5526 (1.04) 0.7312 (1.43) 0.3507 (0.68) 0.5570 (1.07)
logta 0.2222 (0.51) 0.3085 (0.74) 0.6675 (1.39) 0.6942 (1.42)
cil/ta 2.7117 (1.44) 3.0167 (1.57) 2.4083 (1.21) 2.7033 (1.34)
liquid 1.3462 (0.92) 1.3215 (0.97) −0.0527 (−0.05) −0.0373 (−0.03)
absgap −3.2555 (−3.91) −3.0656 (−3.78) −3.1305 (−3.70) −3.0252 (−3.60)
after*li 0.2548 (2.53) 0.2648 (2.51)
after*highrate 1.9479 (4.07) 1.7502 (3.89)
after*noincome 0.6255 (2.33) 0.5534 (1.83)

R2 0.7322 0.7358 0.7154 0.7173


N 5397 5327 4977 4907

This table provides the regression results of the following fixed-effect model:
defaultit = μi + β1 aftert + β2 aftert ∗ preotdi + β2 aftert ∗ ddi
k=K
X
+ β3 aftert ∗ pr eotdi ∗ ddi + β X + it .
k=1
The dependent variable, de f aultit , is measured as the ratio of non-performing mortgages to the outstanding
mortgage loans of bank i during quarter t. a f tert is a dummy variable that is set to zero for quarters before and
including 2007Q1, and one after that. pr eotdi is the average value of OTD mortgages to total mortgages during
quarters 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1; ddi is bank i ’s average demand deposits to total deposits ratio during
quarters 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1; μi denotes bank fixed effects; X stands for a set of control variables.
premortgage is the average ratio of mortgage assets to total assets for 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. logta
measures the log of total assets; cil/ta is the ratio of commercial and industrial loans to total assets; liquid is
the bank’s liquid assets to total assets ratio; absgap is the absolute value of one-year maturity gap as a fraction
of total assets. li measures the average loan-to-income ratio of all loans issued by the bank in 2006. highrate
measures the fraction of high-interest-rate loans originated by the bank, and noincome measures the fraction
of loans without income documentation originated by the bank in 2006. Adjusted R-squared and number of
observations are provided in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.

on demand deposits by taking the ratio of demand deposits to total deposits of


the bank. The ratio is computed as the average over the pre-crisis quarters. The
coefficient on the triple-interaction term a f ter ∗ pr eotd ∗ dd measures the
incremental effect of demand deposits on the mortgage default rate of banks
with a higher fraction of demand deposits.
In all specifications, we find a positive and significant coefficient on a f ter ∗
pr eotd consistent with our base results. More notably, we find a significant
negative coefficient on the triple-interaction term. As the fraction of demand
deposits increases, the relationship between OTD lending and mortgage de-
fault rate weakens. A one-standard-deviation increase in the demand deposit
ratio translates into a decrease of 0.24% in default rates, which is approxi-
mately 18% of the sample median of mortgage default rate. Overall, the results
show that high-OTD banks that are funded primarily by demand deposits did

1911
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

not originate excessively risky loans. It is the set of high-OTD banks with-
out heavy reliance on demand deposits that experienced disproportionately
higher default rates in the immediate aftermath of the crisis. Said differently,
the effect of poor incentives created by the participation in the OTD market
is primarily concentrated within banks that raise most of their capital through

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


non-demandable deposits. These results are consistent with the view that de-
mand deposits create an ex ante effect by limiting excessive risk-taking by the
bank. In unreported tests, we include the effects of capital position and de-
mand deposits together in the model and find that the results remain robust.
Taken together, these results show that banks that were predominantly funded
by non-demandable deposits or wholesale market-based sources of funds were
the main originators of inferior-quality mortgages. These findings highlight the
interdependence between a bank’s funding structure and its asset-side activities
(see Song and Thakor 1997). In particular, any regulation designed to address a
bank’s risk-taking behavior on the lending side should also focus on incentive
effects generated by its liability structure.

5. Discussion and conclusion


We argue that the originate-to-distribute model of lending resulted in the orig-
ination of inferior-quality loans in recent years. Using a measure of banks’
participation in the OTD market prior to the onset of the subprime mortgage
crisis, we show that banks with higher OTD participation have higher mortgage
default rates in the later periods. These defaults are concentrated in banks that
were unable to sell their OTD loans after the disruption in the mortgage mar-
ket. Our evidence confirms the popular belief that lack of screening incentive
created by the separation of origination from the ultimate bearer of the default
risk has been a contributing factor to the current mortgage crisis. Equally im-
portant, our study shows that these incentive problems are severe for poorly
capitalized banks and banks that rely less on demand deposits. Thus, a large
capital base and higher fraction of demand deposits act as disciplining devices
for the banks.
These findings have important implications for financial markets and bank
regulators. They provide useful inputs to the regulation of financial markets
and the determination of capital ratio for the banking sector. Our results also
imply that the probability of default of a mortgage depends on the originator
of the loan in a predictable way. These findings can serve as important inputs
to the pricing models of mortgage-backed securities.

Appendix: Variable construction from call report


We obtain data from quarterly call reports filed by FDIC-insured commercial banks.

• Liquid assets: We define liquid assets as the sum of cash plus federal funds sold plus govern-
ment securities (U.S. treasuries and government agency debt) held by the banks. Note that we

1912
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

do not include all securities held by banks, since they also include mortgage-backed securities.
In our sample period, these securities are unlikely to serve as a liquidity buffer for the banks.
Liquidity ratio is the ratio of liquid assets to total assets.
• Mortgage loans: We take loans granted for 1–4 family residential properties.
• Mortgage chargeoffs and NPA: We take net chargeoff (net or recoveries) on the residential 1–4

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


family mortgages. We consider all mortgage loans that are past due 30 days or more and loans
that are delinquent as non-performing mortgages, or as mortgages under default.
• Originate-to-distribute mortgages: We compute the dollar volume of 1–4 family residential
mortgages originated by banks with a purpose to sell them off to third parties. This data item
is filed by all banks with assets of more than $1 billion as of June 30, 2005, or any bank with
less than $1 billion in total assets where there is more than $10 million activity in the 1–4 fam-
ily residential mortgage market for two consecutive quarters. The first quarter in which banks
reported this data item is 2006Q3. The data are divided into two broad categories: retail origi-
nation and wholesale origination. We divide the sum of retail and wholesale origination by the
beginning of the quarter 1–4 family mortgage loans to get the measure of OTD in our analysis.
We compute the average value of this number based on 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1 to con-
struct a bank-specific measure of participation in the OTD lending. If an observation is missing
for any of these quarters, we compute the average value based on remaining observations.
• Loans sold during the quarter: Banks also report the extent of 1–4 family residential mortgage
loans sold to third parties during the quarter. We scale them by the beginning of the quarter
mortgage loans for 1–4 family residential properties to get the first measure of the intensity of
loan sale. In the second measure, we add the origination of loans during the same quarter to the
beginning of the quarter mortgage loans in the denominator.

• Maturity gap: We construct a one-year maturity GAP as follows: loans and leases due to mature
and re-price within a year + Securities due to mature or re-price within a year + Fed Fund Sold
+ Customer’s Liability to the Bank for Outstanding Acceptance) minus (Term Deposits due
to mature or re-price within a year + Fed Funds Borrowed + Other Liabilities for Borrowed
Funds + Bank’s Liabilities on Customer’s Outstanding Acceptance. We take the absolute value
of this number and scale it by the total assets of the bank to compute the one-year maturity gap
ratio.

References
Allen, F. 2009. The Global Financial Crisis. Paper, Wharton Finance Club.

Allen, F., and E. Carletti. 2006. Credit Risk Transfer and Contagion. Journal of Monetary Economics 53:89–111.

Allen, F., and D. Gale. 1994. Financial Innovations and Risk Sharing. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Ashcraft, A., and J. Santos. 2007. Has the CDS Market Lowered the Cost of Corporate Debt? Working Paper,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Bertrand, M., E. Duflo, and S. Mullainathan. 2004. How Much Should We Trust Differences-in-differences
Estimates? Quarterly Journal of Economics 119:249–75.

Brunnermeier, M. 2009. Deciphering the 2007–2008 Liquidity and Credit Crunch. Journal of Economic Per-
spective 23:77–100.

Calomoris, C., and C. Kahn. 1991. The Role of Demandable Debt in Structuring Optimal Banking Arrange-
ments. American Economic Review 81:497–513.

Dell’Ariccia, G., I. Deniz, and L. A. Laeven. 2008. Credit Booms and Lending Standards: Evidence from the
Subprime Mortgage Market. Working Paper, International Monetary Fund.

1913
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011

Demyanyk, Y., and O. Van Hemert. 2009. Understanding the Subprime Mortgage Crisis. Review of Financial
Studies. Advance Access published May 4, 2009, 10.1093/rfs/hhp033.

Diamond, D., and P. Dybvig. 1983. Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity. Journal of Political Economy
91:401–19.

Doms, M., F. Furlong, and J. Krainer. 2007, Subprime Mortgage Delinquency Rates. Working Paper, Federal

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

Diamond, D., and R. Rajan. 2001. Liquidity Risk, Liquidity Creation, and Financial Fragility: A Theory of
Banking. Journal of Political Economy 109:287–327.

Drucker, S., and M. Puri. 2005. Banks and Capital Markets: A Survey. In Handbook of Empirical Corporate
Finance, ed. B. Espen Eckbo. Elsevier/North-Holland.

. 2009. On Loan Sales, Loan Contracting, and Lending Relationships. Review of Financial Studies
22:2835–72.

Flannery, M. 1994. Debt Maturity Structure and the Deadweight Cost of Leverage: Optimally Financing Banking
Firms. American Economic Review 84:320–31.

Froot, K. A., D. S. Scharfstein, and J. C. Stein. 1993. Risk Management: Coordinating Corporate Investments
and Financing Policies. Journal of Finance 5:1629–58.

Froot, K. A., and J. C. Stein. 1998. Risk Management, Capital Budgeting, and Capital Structure Policy for
Financial Institutions: An Integrated Approach. Journal of Financial Economics 47:55–82.

Gande, A., and A. Saunders. 2007. Are Banks Still Special When There Is a Secondary Market for Loans?
Working Paper, New York University.

Goetzmann, W. N., and M. Spiegel. 1997. A Spatial Model of Housing Returns and Neighborhood Substitutabil-
ity. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 14:11–31.

Gordon, B., and A. D’Silva. 2008. Hedges in the Warehouse: The Banks Get Trimmed. Chicago Fed Letter
#249.

Gorton, G., and G. Pennacchi. 1995. Banks and Loan Sales: Marketing Nonmarketable Assets. Journal of
Monetary Economics 35:389–411.

Greenlaw, D., J. Hatzius, A. K. Kashyap, and H. S. Shin. 2008. Leveraged Losses: Lessons from the Mortgage
Market Meltdown. U.S. Monetary Policy Forum Conference Draft.

Jensen, M., and W. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership
Structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3:305–60.

Holmstrom, B., and J. Tirole. 1997. Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and the Real Sector. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 112:663–91.

. 1998. Private and Public Supply of Liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 106:1–40.

Keys, B., T. Mukherjee, A. Seru, and V. Vig. 2010. Did Securitization Lead to Lax Screening? Evidence from
Subprime Loans. Quarterly Journal of Economics 125:307–62.

Leland, H., and D. Pyle. 1977. Information Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and Financial Intermediation.
Journal of Finance 32:371–87.

Loutskina, E., and P. E. Strahan. 2008. Informed and Uninformed Investment in Housing: The Downside of
Diversification. Working Paper, SSRN.

Mayer, C., and K. Pence. 2008. Subprime Mortgages: What, Where, and to Whom? Working Paper, NBER.

Mian, A., and A. Sufi. 2009. The Consequences of Mortgage Credit Expansion: Evidence from the 2007 Mort-
gage Default Crisis. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124:1449–96.

Mishkin, F. S. 2008. On Leveraged Losses: Lessons from the Mortgage Meltdown. U.S. Monetary Policy Forum
Speech, February 29.

1914
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis

Parlour, C., and G. Plantin. 2008. Loan Sales and Relationship Banking. Journal of Finance 63:1291–314.

Pennacchi, G. 1988. Loan Sales and the Cost of Bank Capital. Journal of Finance 43:375–96.

Petersen, M., and R. Rajan. 1994. The Benefits of Lending Relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data.
Journal of Finance 49:3–37.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article/24/6/1881/1584836 by University of Exeter user on 24 October 2020


Purnanandam, A. 2007. Interest Rate Derivatives at Commercial Banks: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of
Monetary Economics 54:1769–808.

Rajan, U., A. Seru, and V. Vig. 2009. The Failure of Models That Predict Failure: Distance, Incentives, and
Defaults. Working Paper, University of Chicago.

Smith, C. W., and R. Stulz. 1985. The Determinants of Firms’ Hedging Policies. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 28:391–405.

Song, F., and A. Thakor. 1997. Relationship Banking, Fragility, and the Asset-liability Matching Problem. Re-
view of Financial Studies 20:2129–77.

Stein, J. 1998. An Adverse-selection Model of Bank Asset and Liability Management with Implications for the
Transmission of Monetary Policy. RAND Journal of Economics 29:466–86.

. 2002. Information Production and Capital Allocation: Decentralized versus Hierarchical Firms. Journal
of Finance 57:1891–921.

Stulz, R. 1984. Optimal Hedging Policies. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 19:127–40.

Thakor, A. 1996. Capital Requirement, Monetary Policy, and Aggregate Bank Lending: Theory and Empirical
Evidence. Journal of Finance 51:279–324.

Titman, S., and S. Tsyplakov. 2010. Originator Performance, CMBS Structures, and the Risk of Commercial
Mortgages. Review of Financial Studies, 23:3558–94.

Tufano, P. 2003. Financial Innovations. In Handbook of the Economics of Finance, ed. George Constantinides,
Milt Harris, and Rene Stulz. Amsterdam: North Holland.

1915

You might also like