Purnanandam 2010
Purnanandam 2010
The recent crisis in the mortgage market is having an enormous impact on the
world economy. While the popular press has presented a number of anecdotes
and case studies, a body of academic research is fast evolving to understand
the precise causes and consequences of this crisis (see Greenlaw et al. 2008;
Brunnermeier 2009). Our study contributes to this growing literature by an-
alyzing the effect of banks’ participation in the originate-to-distribute (OTD)
method of lending on the crisis.
As a part of their core operation, banks develop considerable expertise in
screening and monitoring their borrowers to minimize the costs of adverse
selection and moral hazard. It is possible that they are not able to take full ad-
vantage of this expertise due to market incompleteness, regulatory reasons, or
some other frictions. For example, regulatory capital requirements and frictions
I thank Sugato Bhattacharya, Uday Rajan, and George Pennacchi for extensive discussions and detailed com-
ments on the article. I want to thank an anonymous referee, Franklin Allen, Heitor Almeida, Sreedhar Bharath,
Charles Calomiris, Sudheer Chava, Douglas Diamond, Gary Fissel, Scott Frame, Chris James, Han Kim, Paul
Kupiec, Pete Kyle, M. P. Narayanan, Paolo Pasquariello, Raghuram Rajan, Joao Santos, Antoinette Schoar,
Amit Seru, Matt Spiegel, Bhaskaran Swaminathan, Sheridan Titman, Anjan Thakor, Peter Tufano, Haluk Unal,
Otto Van Hemert, Paul Willen, and seminar participants at the Board of Governors, Washington, D.C., FDIC,
Michigan State University, Loyola College, University of Texas at Dallas, University of Wisconsin-Madison,
Washington University, York University, AFA 2010, WFA 2009, FIRS 2010, Bank of Portugal Financial In-
termediation Conference 2009, and Texas Finance Festival 2009 for valuable suggestions. Kuncheng Zheng
provided excellent research assistance. I gratefully acknowledge financial support from the FDIC’s Center for
Financial Research. All remaining errors are mine. Send correspondence to Amiyatosh Purnanandam, Ross
School of Business, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 48109; telephone: (734) 764-6886. E-mail: amiy-
atos@umich.edu.
c The Author 2010. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Society for Financial Studies.
All rights reserved. For Permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oup.com.
doi:10.1093/rfs/hhq106 Advance Access publication October 14, 2010
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
in raising external capital might prohibit a bank from lending up to the first-best
level (Stein 1998). Financial innovations naturally arise as a market response to
these frictions (Tufano 2003; Allen and Gale 1994). The originate-to-distribute
(OTD) model of lending, where the originator of loans sells them to third par-
ties, emerged as a solution to some of these frictions. This model allows the
1 Allen and Carletti (2006) analyze conditions under which credit-risk transfer from banking to some other sector
leads to risk-sharing benefits. They also argue that under certain conditions, these risk-transfer tools can lead to
welfare-decreasing outcomes.
2 See Drucker and Puri (2005) for a survey of different theories behind loan sales.
3 The mortgage market was functioning normally until the first quarter of 2007. In March 2007, several subprime
mortgage lenders filed for bankruptcy, providing some early signals of the oncoming mortgage crisis. The sign of
stress in this market became visibly clear by the middle of 2007 (Greenlaw, Hatzius, Kashyap, and Shin 2008).
1882
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
pressure in the middle of 2007, banks with a higher volume of OTD loans were
stuck with large quantities of relatively inferior-quality mortgage loans. It can
take about two to three quarters from the origination to the sale of these loans in
the secondary market (Gordon and D’Silva 2008). In addition, the originators
typically guarantee the loan performance for the first 90 days of loans (Mishkin
1883
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
4 Since the capital structure and the demand deposit mix of large banks are generally very different from those of
the small banks, we pay careful attention to the effect of bank size in these tests.
1884
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
structure have important implications for the pricing of assets in the secondary
market. It is important to note that our results come from a period of turmoil
in the financial markets. To draw strong policy implications, one obviously
has to compare these costs of securitization with the potential benefits of risk-
management tools (Stulz 1984; Smith and Stulz 1985; Froot, Scharfstein, and
1. Data
We use two sources of data for our study: the call report database for bank in-
formation and the HMDA (Home Mortgage Disclosure Act) database for loan
details. All Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)-insured commer-
cial banks are required to file call reports with the regulators on a quarterly
basis. These reports contain detailed information on the bank’s income state-
ment, balance-sheet items, and off-balance-sheet activities. The items required
to be filed in this report change over time to reflect the changing nature of bank-
ing business. As the mortgage sale and securitization activities grew in recent
years, there have been concomitant improvements in the quality of reporting
with respect to these items as well.
Beginning with the third quarter of 2006, banks started to report two key
items regarding their mortgage activities: (a) the origination of 1–4 family
residential mortgages during the quarter with a purpose to resell in the market;
and (b) the extent of 1–4 family residential mortgages actually sold during the
quarter. These variables allow us to measure the extent of participation in the
OTD market as well as the extent of loans that were actually offloaded by a
bank in a given quarter. Both items are provided in schedule RC-P of the call
report. This schedule is required to be filed by banks with $1 billion or more in
total assets and by smaller banks if they exceed $10 million in their mortgage-
selling activities. The data, in effect, are available for all banks that participate
significantly in the OTD market.
5 See also Ashcraft and Santos (2008) for a study on the costs and benefits of credit default swaps, and Gande and
Saunders (2007) for the effect of the secondary loan sales market on the bank-specialness.
1885
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
We construct our key measure of OTD activity as the ratio of loans origi-
nated for resale during the quarter scaled by the beginning of the quarter mort-
gage loans of the bank. This ratio captures the extent of a bank’s participation
in the OTD market as a fraction of its overall mortgage portfolio. We measure
the extent of selling in the OTD market as the ratio of loans sold during the
1886
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
1887
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
Figure 3
Mortgage chargeoff over time
The figure plots the average net chargeoff as a percentage of mortgage outstanding on a quarterly basis. Quarter
zero corresponds to the quarter ending on March 31, 2007.
banks, due to the fact that we require data on OTD mortgage origination and
sale for a bank to be available to be included in our sample. We provide the
distribution of other key variables in the table. These numbers are in line with
other studies involving large bank samples.
1888
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
Table 1
Summary statistics
variable N mean p50 min max
ta 5397.00 5.92 1.05 0.06 168.65
mortgage/ta 5397.00 0.17 0.15 0.01 0.49
cil/ta 5397.00 0.11 0.10 0.00 0.39
This table provides the summary statistics of key variables used in the study. All variables are computed using
call report data for seven quarters starting from 2006Q3 and ending in 2008Q1. We provide the number of
observations (N), mean, median, minimum, and maximum values for each variable. ta is total assets in billions
of dollars; mortgage/ta is the ratio of 1–4 family residential mortgages outstanding to total assets; cil/ta is the
ratio of commercial and industrial loans to total assets; td/ta is the ratio of total deposits to total assets; dd/td is
the ratio of demand deposits to total deposits; nii/ta is the ratio of net interest income to total assets; chargeoff
measures the chargeoff on mortgage portfolio (net of recoveries) as a percentage of mortgage assets; npa/ta
is the ratio of non-performing assets to total assets; mortnpa is the ratio of non-performing mortgages to total
mortgages; tier1cap measures the ratio of tier-one capital to risk-adjusted assets; liquid is the bank’s liquid assets
to total assets ratio, absgap is the absolute value of one-year maturity gap as a fraction of total assets. preotd
measures the originate-to-distribute loans, i.e., mortgages originated with a purpose to sell, as a fraction of total
mortgages. This variable is constructed at the bank level based on its average quarterly values during 2006Q3,
2006Q4, and 2007Q1.
6 Our results are robust to alternative ways of constructing this variable; for example, by averaging over only
2006Q3 and 2006Q4 or by only taking 2007Q1 value as the measure of preotd.
1889
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
remarkable linear increase over this time period. The difference in default rate
becomes especially high after a couple of quarters from the onset of the crisis.
In summary, we find that banks with higher OTD participation before the
subprime mortgage crisis increased their chargeoffs significantly more than
banks with lower OTD. Are these differences significant after accounting for
differences in bank characteristics and the quality of borrowers they face? And
why does this difference exist across the two groups? We explore these ques-
tions through formal econometric tests in the rest of the article.
1890
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
enough liquidity, banks were able to offload their originated loans without
any disruption. The delay from origination to the final sale of these loans did
not impose significant credit risk on the originating banks during normal pe-
riods. However, when the secondary mortgage market came under pressure
in the middle of 2007, banks with high-OTD loans were stuck with dispro-
7 Our results are similar if we add the mortgages originated during the quarter in the denominator.
1891
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
variable that measures the extent of bank i’s participation in the OTD market
prior to the disruption in this market in the middle of 2007. We expect to find
a positive and significant coefficient on this variable because banks with large
OTD loans, almost by construction, are more likely to sell large quantities
of these loans in the secondary market. a f tert is an indicator variable that
8 Our results are similar without the inclusion of the pr emor tgage variable in the regression models.
1892
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
Table 2
Intensity of mortgages sold
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat
preotd 0.9591 (54.64)
k=K
X
soldit = β0 + β1 a f tert + β2 pr eotdi + β3 a f tert ∗ pr eotdi + β X + it .
k=1
The dependent variable, soldit , measures bank i ’s mortgage sale as a fraction of its total mortgage loans at the
beginning of quarter t . a f tert is a dummy variable that is set to zero for quarters before and including 2007Q1,
and one after that. pr eotdi is the average value of OTD mortgages to total mortgages during quarters 2006Q3,
2006Q4, and 2007Q1. X stands for a set of control variables. Model 1 is estimated using the OLS method.
Models 2 and 3 are estimated with bank fixed effects. Model 3 excludes banks with more than $10 billion in
assets. These models omit pr eotd and pr emor tgage as right-hand-side variables since they remain constant
across all seven quarters for a given bank. premortgage is the average ratio of mortgage assets to total assets
for 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. logta measures the log of total assets; cil/ta is the ratio of commercial and
industrial loans to total assets; liquid is the bank’s liquid assets to total asset ratio; absgap is the absolute value of
one-year maturity gap as a fraction of total assets. Adjusted R-squared and number of observations are provided
in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.
estimate of −0.0251 with t-statistics of −2.74). These findings show that the
decline in mortgage resale is concentrated among high pr eotd banks. In Model
3, we re-estimate the fixed-effect model after removing banks with more than
$10 billion in asset size from the sample because it is often argued that large
money-centric banks have a different business model than regional and local
banks. We find that our results are equally strong after excluding these large
banks from the sample.
These results are economically significant as well. For example, a one-
standard-deviation increase in OTD lending prior to the disruption results in
a decline of 10% in selling intensity after the crisis based on the estimates of
Model 2. Overall, these results are consistent with our assertion that the dis-
ruption in the mortgage market created warehousing risk for the banks, which
in turn led to an accumulation of undesired loans; i.e., loans that were initially
intended to be sold but could not be sold due to an unexpected decline in the
market conditions.
1893
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
The dependent variable of this model measures the default rate of the mortgage
portfolio of bank i in quarter t. We use two measures of default: net-chargeoffs
and non-performing mortgages; i.e., mortgages that are in default for more than
30 days. We scale them by the bank’s total mortgage loans measured as of the
beginning of the quarter. μi stands for bank fixed effects, and X it is a vec-
tor of bank characteristics.9 The coefficient on the a f ter variable captures the
time trend in default rate before and after the mortgage crisis. The coefficient
on the interaction term (i.e., a f tert ∗ pr eotdi ) measures the change in char-
geoffs/NPAs around the crisis period across banks with varying intensities of
participation in the OTD market prior to the crisis. Said differently, β2 mea-
sures the change in default rate for banks that originated loans primarily to sell
them to third parties, as compared with the corresponding change for banks
that originated loans primarily to retain them on their own balance sheets. We
include the interaction of a f ter with pr emor tgage to ensure that the relation-
ship between OTD loans and mortgage performance is not simply an artifact
of higher involvement in mortgage lending by higher OTD banks.10
We control for a host of bank characteristics that can potentially affect the
quality of mortgage loans. We control for the bank’s size by including the log
of total assets in the regression model. We include the ratio of commercial and
industrial loans to total assets to control for the broad business mix of the bank.
A measure of the 12-month maturity gap is included to control for the interest-
rate risk faced by the banks. Finally, we include the ratio of liquid assets to
total assets to control for the liquidity position. The last three variables broadly
capture the extent and nature of credit risk, interest-rate risk, and liquidity risk
faced by the banks.
Table 3 provides the results. We provide results for the entire sample in
Models 1 and 2. In Models 3 and 4, we exclude large banks with asset size
more than $10 billion from the sample. We find that the extent of participation
in the OTD market during the pre-disruption period has a significant effect
9 In an alternative specification, we also estimate this model without bank fixed effects (similar to the one de-
scribed in the previous section for the extent of mortgage resale). The advantage of this model is that it also
allows us to estimate the coefficient on pr eotd . However, we prefer the bank fixed-effect approach as it allows
us to control for unobservable factors that are time-invariant and unique to a bank. All key results remain similar
for the alternative econometric model.
10 We re-estimate these models without including the interaction of a f ter and pr emor tgage and obtain similar
results.
1894
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
Table 3
Mortgage defaults
All Banks Excludes Large Banks
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Chargeoffs NPA Chargeoffs NPA
This table provides the regression results of the following fixed-effects model:
k=K
X
defaultit = μi + β1 aftert + β2 aftert ∗ preotdi + β X + it .
k=1
The dependent variable, de f aultit , is measured by either the mortgage chargeoffs or the non-performing mort-
gages (scaled by the outstanding mortgage loans) of bank i during quarter t . a f tert is a dummy variable that is
set to zero for quarters before and including 2007Q1, and one after that. pr eotdi is the average value of OTD
mortgages to total mortgages during quarters 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. μi denotes bank fixed effects;
X stands for a set of control variables. premortgage is the average ratio of mortgage assets to total assets for
2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. logta measures the log of total assets; cil/ta is the ratio of commercial and in-
dustrial loans to total assets; liquid is the bank’s liquid assets to total assets ratio; absgap is the absolute value of
one-year maturity gap as a fraction of total assets. Adjusted R-squared and number of observations are provided
in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.
11 In an unreported robustness exercise, we drop the first two quarters after the beginning of the crisis from our
sample. We do so to allow more time for the mortgages to default after the beginning of the crisis. Our results
become slightly stronger for this specification.
1895
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
Table 4
Mortgage default and inability to sell
All Banks Excludes Large Banks
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Chargeoffs NPA Chargeoffs NPA
This table provides regression results for the following fixed-effect model:
k=K
X
de f aultit = μi + β1 a f tert + β2 a f tert ∗ stucki + β X + it .
k=1
The dependent variable, de f aultit , is measured by either the mortgage chargeoffs or the non-performing mort-
gages of bank i during quarter t . a f tert is a dummy variable that is set to zero for quarters before and including
2007Q1, and one after that. stucki measures the difference between loans originated before 2007Q1 and loans
sold after this quarter. μi denotes bank fixed effects; X stands for a set of control variables. premortgage is the
average ratio of mortgage assets to total assets for 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. logta measures the log of
total assets; cil/ta is the ratio of commercial and industrial loans to total assets; liquid is the bank’s liquid assets
to total assets ratio; absgap is the absolute value of one-year maturity gap as a fraction of total assets. Adjusted
R-squared and number of observations are provided in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the
bank level.
12 It is worth pointing out that this measure is not a perfect proxy for stuck loans because it does not directly match
loan origination with selling at the loan-by-loan level. However, in the absence of detailed loan-level data, it is a
reasonable proxy for the cross-sectional dispersion of stuck loans at the bank level.
1896
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
Overall, we show that OTD loans were of inferior quality because banks that
were stuck with these loans in the post-disruption period had disproportion-
ately higher chargeoffs and borrower defaults. While these results are consis-
tent with the hypothesis of dilution in screening standards of high-OTD banks,
there are two important alternative explanations: (a) Do high-OTD banks ex-
1897
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
dimensions of credit risk to rule out this hypothesis. We divide sample banks
into two groups (above and below median) based on their involvement in the
OTD market prior to the disruption (i.e., pr eotd variable). Our goal is to match
every high-OTD bank with a low-OTD bank that has made mortgages in a sim-
ilar geographical area to observationally similar borrowers.
13 We have estimated the model without this restriction, and all results remain similar.
1898
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
15 Since we impose a restriction of balanced panel in our study, in regressions we lose few observation due to the
non-availability of other data items for all seven quarters. Our results remain robust to the inclusion of these
observations in the sample.
1899
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
Figure 5
Distribution of key characteristics of high- and low-OTD banks after matching
The plots give the kernel density functions of the key characteristics of the high- and low-OTD banks after
matching. More details on the matching are provided in the article. The first plot is for the loan-to-income ratios;
the second plot is for the borrowers’ annual income.
The coefficient on a f ter ∗ pr eotd is almost twice as much as the base case
that uses all bank-quarter observations. However, we cannot compare these
two estimates directly because they are estimated on different samples.
1900
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
Table 5
Matched sample analysis: Base case
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
NPA NPA NPA NPA
Dependent Var: Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat
This table reports the estimation results of fixed-effect regressions on a matched sample of high- and low-OTD
banks. Banks are matched on geographical location of their mortgage portfolios, the borrowers’ loan-to-income
ratio, the borrowers’ annual income, and the bank’s size. The dependent variable is the non-performing mortgage
loans of banks in a given quarter. The definitions of variables and details of the model estimation are provided in
the article. Adjusted R-squared and number of observations are provided in the bottom rows. All standard errors
are clustered at the bank level.
Overall, the analysis of this section shows that the variation generated by the
OTD model of lending is unlikely to be explained away by differences in bor-
rower’s credit risk, property location, bank size, or other bank characteristics.
1901
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
subprime category. Though we are unable to match on loan spreads for the en-
tire mortgage portfolio, it is this subset that is more meaningful in terms of our
economic exercise. We compute the average loan spread on a bank-by-bank
basis and then match banks based on these averages.
For every high-OTD bank, we first find a set of low-OTD banks that meet
1902
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
Table 6
Matched sample analysis: Average loan spread charged
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
NPA NPA NPA NPA
Dependent Var: Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat
This table reports the estimation results of fixed-effect regressions on a matched sample of high- and low-OTD
banks. Banks are matched on geographical location of their mortgage portfolios, bank size, the borrowers’ loan-
to-income ratio, and the average rate spread on the subprime loan portfolio of the bank. The dependent variable
is the non-performing mortgage loans of the banks in a given quarter. The definition of variables and details of
the model estimation are provided in the article. Adjusted R-squared and number of observations are provided
in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.
used in the process of lending should ultimately be reflected in the rate that
banks charge their borrowers. Thus, by exploiting the variation along the OTD
dimension, while keeping the interest rates similar, we are able to more pre-
cisely estimate the effect of securitization on screening.
Table 6 shows the results. In Models 1 and 2, we estimate the effect of
pr eotd and stuck variables on mortgage default rates without controlling for
other bank characteristics. Models 3 and 4 include control variables as well.
We find strong evidence that banks that originated a large volume of mort-
gages that were intended to be sold in the OTD market experienced larger
mortgage default on their portfolios in quarters immediately following the cri-
sis. The effect is stronger for banks that were unable to sell these loans. A
one-standard-deviation increase in OTD lending in the pre-crisis period results
in an increase of 0.38% in the mortgage default rate after the crisis. This in-
crease is approximately 26% of the matched sample’s median mortgage default
rate.
Even for banks that charged similar rates to their borrowers and made most
of their loans in the same geographical area, the performance of high-OTD
banks is significantly worse in the post-disruption period. Conditional on inter-
est rates, there should be no relationship between OTD lending and post-crisis
default rates if these two groups of loans were made with equal screening ef-
forts. However, if high-OTD loans were granted without proper screening on
unobservable dimensions, then we are likely to find higher default rates for
high-OTD banks even within this sample. The evidence of this section sug-
gests that OTD loans were made without proper screening on unobservable
dimensions.
1903
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
riski represents a vector of borrowers’ default risk for bank i. We interact these
measures with a f ter to separate out the effect of borrower risk characteristics
on default rates after the crisis from the bank’s OTD lending. We use several
measures of default risk, such as loan-to-income ratio, annual income, average
interest rate charged by the bank, fraction of subprime loans in a bank’s port-
folio, and the fraction of low-documentation loans in its portfolio. Our results
remain robust to this alternative specification. To save space, we do not present
these results in the article.
1904
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
1905
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
Table 7
Matched sample analysis: Small to big
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
NPA NPA NPA NPA
Dependent Var: Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat Estimate t-stat
This table reports the estimation results of fixed-effect regressions on a matched sample of high- and low-OTD
banks. We match small banks with large OTD lending with large banks with little to no OTD lending. The
dependent variable is the non-performing mortgage loans of the banks in a given quarter. The definitions of
variables and details of the model estimation are provided in the article. Adjusted R-squared and number of
observations are provided in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.
bank discriminates its borrowers significantly more than the NS bank for the
same set of observable characteristics of the borrowers. Therefore, loan rates
charged by the S bank will have a wider distribution than the loan rates charged
by the NS bank for observationally equivalent borrowers. Thus, if the high-
OTD banks are of the NS type, then we expect to observe tighter distribution
of loan rates for these banks after parsing out the effect of observable signals.
This test is in line with the arguments developed more formally in Rajan, Seru,
and Vig (2009), who argue that the default prediction models fail in systematic
ways as the reliance on hard information in loan-approval decisions increases.
Based on this idea, we compare the distribution of loan spreads charged to
borrowers across high- and low-OTD banks. We first obtain all loan-level ob-
servation from the HMDA data with non-missing observation on loan spreads.
As discussed earlier, these data are reported for very high-risk borrowers only;
i.e., for the subset for which the effect of lax screening is potentially higher.
We first estimate the following model of loan spread to parse out the effect of
observable characteristics:
rateib = α + β X ib + ib .
rateib is the log percentage spread (over comparable maturity treasury secu-
rity) on mortgage to borrower i by bank b. X ib is a set of borrower, loan, and
bank characteristics that are observable and likely to affect the loan rate. We
include the following borrower characteristics in the model: log of borrower’s
annual income, log of loan amount, loan-to-income ratio, log of neighborhood
median family income reported by HMDA, percentage minority population in
the neighborhood, whether the loan is secured by a first lien or not, whether the
property is occupied by the owner or not, purpose of the loan (home purchase,
1906
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
Table 8
Shrinkage in loan spread
Panel A: All Banks Panel B: Matched Sample
High OTD Low OTD Shrinkage High OTD Low OTD Shrinkage
Standard Deviation 0.2236 0.2621 0.0385 0.2056 0.2627 0.0571
This table provides the dispersion in loan spread across high- (above-median) and low- (below-median) OTD
banks. Panel A is for all banks, and Panel B for the matched sample. We provide three measures of dispersion
in log loan spreads: standard deviation, the difference between the 75th and 25th percentiles, and the difference
between the 90th and 10th percentiles. Shrinkage measures the difference in dispersion across the high- and
low-OTD banks. Bartlett’s and Levene’s p-values are for the null hypothesis that the variance of loan spreads for
the high-OTD group equals the variance of loan spreads for the low-OTD group.
16 We have experimented with several other reasonable specifications and obtained similar results. We report results
based on one of the most comprehensive models to isolate the effect of observable information on loan spreads.
1907
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
Overall, we show that the low-OTD banks offered loans at more discrim-
inating terms for the same observable characteristics as compared with the
high-OTD banks. This finding is consistent with the assertion that the high-
OTD banks did not expend as much resources in screening their borrowers as
their low-OTD counterparts.
The dependent variable, de f aultit , measures the mortgage default rate of bank
i in quarter t. capi measures the tier-one capital ratio of bank i during the
1908
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
Table 9
The effect of bank capital
All Banks Excludes Large Banks
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
NPA NPA NPA NPA
This table provides the regression results of the following fixed-effect model:
defaultit = μi + β1 aftert + β2 aftert ∗ preotdi + β2 aftert ∗ capi
k=K
X
+ β3 aftert ∗ preotdi ∗ capi + β X + it .
k=1
The dependent variable, de f aultit , is measured as the ratio of non-performing mortgages to the outstanding
mortgage loans of bank i during quarter t. a f tert is a dummy variable that is set to zero for quarters before and
including 2007Q1, and one after that. pr eotdi is the average value of OTD mortgages to total mortgages during
quarters 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1; capi is bank i ’s average tier-one capital ratio during quarters 2006Q3,
2006Q4, and 2007Q1; μi denotes bank fixed effects; X stands for a set of control variables. premortgage is the
average ratio of mortgage assets to total assets for 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. logta measures the log of total
assets; cil/ta is the ratio of commercial and industrial loans to total assets; liquid is the bank’s liquid assets to
total assets ratio; absgap is the absolute value of one-year maturity gap as a fraction of total assets. li measures
the average loan-to-income ratio of all loans issued by the bank in 2006. highrate measures the fraction of
high-interest-rate loans originated by the bank, and noincome measures the fraction of loans without income
documentation originated by the bank in 2006. Adjusted R-squared and number of observations are provided in
the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.
pre-disruption quarters. We take the average value of this ratio for the pre-
disruption quarters (2006Q3 to 2007Q1) to capture the effect of the capital
ratio at the time these loans were made. Table 9 provides the estimation results.
Consistent with our earlier analysis, we present results for both the “All Bank”
sample and the “Excluding Large Banks” subsample. In Models 1 and 3, we
estimate the regression model with bank-level control variables only. Models
2 and 4 control for borrower characteristics based on the HMDA dataset for
2006.
It is important to note that banks choose their capital ratios endogenously.
This raises a potential concern for our identification strategy in this section. For
example, consider a bank CEO who prefers higher risk for some unobserved
reasons. A bank with such a CEO is likely to keep lower capital and at the
same time originate riskier loans in the OTD market. Our triple-difference tests
1909
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
exploit variations within the set of high-OTD banks. Said differently, the coef-
ficient on the triple-interaction term measures the incremental effect of capital
constraints, holding fixed the level of OTD loans. The unconditional effect of
capital constraint is captured by the double-interaction term a f ter ∗ cap. The
test design, therefore, minimizes the endogeneity concerns to a large extent.
1910
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
Table 10
The effect of demand deposits
All Banks Excludes Large Banks
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
NPA NPA NPA NPA
This table provides the regression results of the following fixed-effect model:
defaultit = μi + β1 aftert + β2 aftert ∗ preotdi + β2 aftert ∗ ddi
k=K
X
+ β3 aftert ∗ pr eotdi ∗ ddi + β X + it .
k=1
The dependent variable, de f aultit , is measured as the ratio of non-performing mortgages to the outstanding
mortgage loans of bank i during quarter t. a f tert is a dummy variable that is set to zero for quarters before and
including 2007Q1, and one after that. pr eotdi is the average value of OTD mortgages to total mortgages during
quarters 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1; ddi is bank i ’s average demand deposits to total deposits ratio during
quarters 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1; μi denotes bank fixed effects; X stands for a set of control variables.
premortgage is the average ratio of mortgage assets to total assets for 2006Q3, 2006Q4, and 2007Q1. logta
measures the log of total assets; cil/ta is the ratio of commercial and industrial loans to total assets; liquid is
the bank’s liquid assets to total assets ratio; absgap is the absolute value of one-year maturity gap as a fraction
of total assets. li measures the average loan-to-income ratio of all loans issued by the bank in 2006. highrate
measures the fraction of high-interest-rate loans originated by the bank, and noincome measures the fraction
of loans without income documentation originated by the bank in 2006. Adjusted R-squared and number of
observations are provided in the bottom rows. All standard errors are clustered at the bank level.
1911
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
not originate excessively risky loans. It is the set of high-OTD banks with-
out heavy reliance on demand deposits that experienced disproportionately
higher default rates in the immediate aftermath of the crisis. Said differently,
the effect of poor incentives created by the participation in the OTD market
is primarily concentrated within banks that raise most of their capital through
• Liquid assets: We define liquid assets as the sum of cash plus federal funds sold plus govern-
ment securities (U.S. treasuries and government agency debt) held by the banks. Note that we
1912
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
do not include all securities held by banks, since they also include mortgage-backed securities.
In our sample period, these securities are unlikely to serve as a liquidity buffer for the banks.
Liquidity ratio is the ratio of liquid assets to total assets.
• Mortgage loans: We take loans granted for 1–4 family residential properties.
• Mortgage chargeoffs and NPA: We take net chargeoff (net or recoveries) on the residential 1–4
• Maturity gap: We construct a one-year maturity GAP as follows: loans and leases due to mature
and re-price within a year + Securities due to mature or re-price within a year + Fed Fund Sold
+ Customer’s Liability to the Bank for Outstanding Acceptance) minus (Term Deposits due
to mature or re-price within a year + Fed Funds Borrowed + Other Liabilities for Borrowed
Funds + Bank’s Liabilities on Customer’s Outstanding Acceptance. We take the absolute value
of this number and scale it by the total assets of the bank to compute the one-year maturity gap
ratio.
References
Allen, F. 2009. The Global Financial Crisis. Paper, Wharton Finance Club.
Allen, F., and E. Carletti. 2006. Credit Risk Transfer and Contagion. Journal of Monetary Economics 53:89–111.
Allen, F., and D. Gale. 1994. Financial Innovations and Risk Sharing. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Ashcraft, A., and J. Santos. 2007. Has the CDS Market Lowered the Cost of Corporate Debt? Working Paper,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Bertrand, M., E. Duflo, and S. Mullainathan. 2004. How Much Should We Trust Differences-in-differences
Estimates? Quarterly Journal of Economics 119:249–75.
Brunnermeier, M. 2009. Deciphering the 2007–2008 Liquidity and Credit Crunch. Journal of Economic Per-
spective 23:77–100.
Calomoris, C., and C. Kahn. 1991. The Role of Demandable Debt in Structuring Optimal Banking Arrange-
ments. American Economic Review 81:497–513.
Dell’Ariccia, G., I. Deniz, and L. A. Laeven. 2008. Credit Booms and Lending Standards: Evidence from the
Subprime Mortgage Market. Working Paper, International Monetary Fund.
1913
The Review of Financial Studies / v 24 n 6 2011
Demyanyk, Y., and O. Van Hemert. 2009. Understanding the Subprime Mortgage Crisis. Review of Financial
Studies. Advance Access published May 4, 2009, 10.1093/rfs/hhp033.
Diamond, D., and P. Dybvig. 1983. Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity. Journal of Political Economy
91:401–19.
Doms, M., F. Furlong, and J. Krainer. 2007, Subprime Mortgage Delinquency Rates. Working Paper, Federal
Diamond, D., and R. Rajan. 2001. Liquidity Risk, Liquidity Creation, and Financial Fragility: A Theory of
Banking. Journal of Political Economy 109:287–327.
Drucker, S., and M. Puri. 2005. Banks and Capital Markets: A Survey. In Handbook of Empirical Corporate
Finance, ed. B. Espen Eckbo. Elsevier/North-Holland.
. 2009. On Loan Sales, Loan Contracting, and Lending Relationships. Review of Financial Studies
22:2835–72.
Flannery, M. 1994. Debt Maturity Structure and the Deadweight Cost of Leverage: Optimally Financing Banking
Firms. American Economic Review 84:320–31.
Froot, K. A., D. S. Scharfstein, and J. C. Stein. 1993. Risk Management: Coordinating Corporate Investments
and Financing Policies. Journal of Finance 5:1629–58.
Froot, K. A., and J. C. Stein. 1998. Risk Management, Capital Budgeting, and Capital Structure Policy for
Financial Institutions: An Integrated Approach. Journal of Financial Economics 47:55–82.
Gande, A., and A. Saunders. 2007. Are Banks Still Special When There Is a Secondary Market for Loans?
Working Paper, New York University.
Goetzmann, W. N., and M. Spiegel. 1997. A Spatial Model of Housing Returns and Neighborhood Substitutabil-
ity. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 14:11–31.
Gordon, B., and A. D’Silva. 2008. Hedges in the Warehouse: The Banks Get Trimmed. Chicago Fed Letter
#249.
Gorton, G., and G. Pennacchi. 1995. Banks and Loan Sales: Marketing Nonmarketable Assets. Journal of
Monetary Economics 35:389–411.
Greenlaw, D., J. Hatzius, A. K. Kashyap, and H. S. Shin. 2008. Leveraged Losses: Lessons from the Mortgage
Market Meltdown. U.S. Monetary Policy Forum Conference Draft.
Jensen, M., and W. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership
Structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3:305–60.
Holmstrom, B., and J. Tirole. 1997. Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and the Real Sector. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 112:663–91.
. 1998. Private and Public Supply of Liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 106:1–40.
Keys, B., T. Mukherjee, A. Seru, and V. Vig. 2010. Did Securitization Lead to Lax Screening? Evidence from
Subprime Loans. Quarterly Journal of Economics 125:307–62.
Leland, H., and D. Pyle. 1977. Information Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and Financial Intermediation.
Journal of Finance 32:371–87.
Loutskina, E., and P. E. Strahan. 2008. Informed and Uninformed Investment in Housing: The Downside of
Diversification. Working Paper, SSRN.
Mayer, C., and K. Pence. 2008. Subprime Mortgages: What, Where, and to Whom? Working Paper, NBER.
Mian, A., and A. Sufi. 2009. The Consequences of Mortgage Credit Expansion: Evidence from the 2007 Mort-
gage Default Crisis. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124:1449–96.
Mishkin, F. S. 2008. On Leveraged Losses: Lessons from the Mortgage Meltdown. U.S. Monetary Policy Forum
Speech, February 29.
1914
Originate-to-distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis
Parlour, C., and G. Plantin. 2008. Loan Sales and Relationship Banking. Journal of Finance 63:1291–314.
Pennacchi, G. 1988. Loan Sales and the Cost of Bank Capital. Journal of Finance 43:375–96.
Petersen, M., and R. Rajan. 1994. The Benefits of Lending Relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data.
Journal of Finance 49:3–37.
Rajan, U., A. Seru, and V. Vig. 2009. The Failure of Models That Predict Failure: Distance, Incentives, and
Defaults. Working Paper, University of Chicago.
Smith, C. W., and R. Stulz. 1985. The Determinants of Firms’ Hedging Policies. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 28:391–405.
Song, F., and A. Thakor. 1997. Relationship Banking, Fragility, and the Asset-liability Matching Problem. Re-
view of Financial Studies 20:2129–77.
Stein, J. 1998. An Adverse-selection Model of Bank Asset and Liability Management with Implications for the
Transmission of Monetary Policy. RAND Journal of Economics 29:466–86.
. 2002. Information Production and Capital Allocation: Decentralized versus Hierarchical Firms. Journal
of Finance 57:1891–921.
Stulz, R. 1984. Optimal Hedging Policies. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 19:127–40.
Thakor, A. 1996. Capital Requirement, Monetary Policy, and Aggregate Bank Lending: Theory and Empirical
Evidence. Journal of Finance 51:279–324.
Titman, S., and S. Tsyplakov. 2010. Originator Performance, CMBS Structures, and the Risk of Commercial
Mortgages. Review of Financial Studies, 23:3558–94.
Tufano, P. 2003. Financial Innovations. In Handbook of the Economics of Finance, ed. George Constantinides,
Milt Harris, and Rene Stulz. Amsterdam: North Holland.
1915