Speculation
Speculation
Speculation
Zhenyu Gao
Chinese University of Hong Kong
Wei Xiong
Princeton University, CUHK Shenzhen, and NBER
Received May 28, 2018; editorial decision August 21, 2019 by Editor Itay Goldstein.
Authors have furnished an Internet Appendix, which is available on the Oxford University
Press Web site next to the link to the final published paper online.
This paper supersedes an earlier draft, which was circulated under the title “Housing Speculation and Supply
Overhang.” We thank Itay Goldstein (the editor) and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. We are
grateful to Gene Amromin, Barney Hartman-Glaser, Andrew Haughwout, Zhiguo He, Tim Landvoigt, Alvin
Murphy, Charlie Nathanson, and Monika Piazzesi and seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, the University of Texas at Austin, the Wharton School, the American Economic Association Meetings, the
American Finance Association Meetings, the CICF meetings, the FRB Atlanta, GSU Real Estate Finance, and
the Texas Finance Festival Conference for helpful comments and discussion. Supplementary data can be found
on The Review of Financial Studies web site. Send correspondence to Zhenyu Gao, CUHK Business School, The
Chinese University of Hong Kong, Room 1244, 12/F, Cheng Yu Tung Building, 12 Chak Cheung Street, Shatin,
N.T., Hong Kong telephone: 852-3943-1824. E-mail: gaozhenyu@baf.cuhk.edu.hk.
DeFusco, Nathanson, and Zwick (2017), Nathanson and Zwick (2017), and
Soo (2018), has highlighted the importance of housing speculation in driving
the recent housing cycle.1 Housing speculation became a national phenomenon
in the low-interest-rate environment of the mid-2000s, with purchases of non-
owner-occupied homes (second and investment homes) contributing up to
30% of all home purchases during the boom in cities such as Las Vegas.
Housing speculation also represented a source of housing demand largely
orthogonal to the credit expansion to subprime households that occurred during
the housing boom, which is widely regarded, for instance by Mian and Sufi
1 Glaeser (2013) provides an eloquent analysis of nine episodes of real estate speculation in American history and
highlights housing speculation as one of several recurring themes within the episodes.
2 This opposite and less significant correlation suggests that studies that instrument the housing price boom with
supply elasticity or variation in nonrecourse mortgage laws are capturing the impact of subprime rather than
speculation.
5249
speculation that takes advantage of the variation across U.S. states in their
taxation of capital gains. While homeowners can exclude capital gains from
the sale of their primary residence from their income taxes, this exclusion
does not cover capital gains from selling non-owner-occupied homes. As
U.S. states have significant variation in how they tax capital gains, housing
speculation is more intensive in states with either no or low capital gains taxes.
We therefore construct our instrument as the marginal tax rate for the median
income household in each state.
By instrumenting non-owner-occupied home purchases with the capital gains
5250
demand, as suggested by Mian, Rao, and Sufi (2013) and Mian and Sufi (2014),
by analyzing the impact of housing speculation on nontradable sectors—and
the retail and restaurant sectors more narrowly—which primarily rely on local
consumption demand. We find significant real effects through this channel.
An increase of 1 standard deviation in instrumented housing speculation in
2004–2006 led to a decrease of 15.1% in nontradable sectors’ employment
in 2007–2009, and a decline of 15.6% in the retail and restaurant sectors,
specifically.3 In contrast, housing speculation had a more modest effect on
employment in tradable sectors and in industries other than retail and the
3 Kaplan, Mitman, and Violante (2017), through the lens of a quantitative framework, also find that a shift in
households’ expectations of future capital gains on housing investments deepened the Great Recession through
the household balance sheet channel.
5251
1. Empirical Methodology
We aim to examine the economic impact of housing speculation during the
boom and bust cycle of the U.S. housing markets in the 2000s. The literature
has established that this housing cycle was, in part, driven by a credit expansion
to households across the country, which was precipitated by the rapid growth
5252
of securitization and shadow banking in the early 2000s (e.g., Mian and
Sufi 2009; Keys et al. 2010). While this was a national housing cycle, there
was substantial variation across regions. We are interested in testing whether
housing speculation contributed to this cross-region variation and, specifically,
whether housing speculation during the boom affected the housing cycles and
economic performance during the subsequent downturn.4
To facilitate our cross-region analysis during this national cycle, we divide
the housing cycle into three phases: 2001–2003 as the preboom period, 2004–
2006 as the boom period, and 2007–2009 as the bust period.5 We define
4 We focus on the recent U.S. housing cycle of the 2000s, because the data are more complete for this period
than for earlier years, and because the national housing cycle allows us to directly compare the cross-sectional
variation in housing markets and local economic conditions. Such a cross-sectional analysis is not feasible for
the earlier housing cycles of the 1980s and 1990s, as they were asynchronous and experienced by only a few
cities.
5 This definition is largely consistent with the timing convention in the literature. In particular, 2006 is widely
recognized as the turning point of the cycle, as noted by Glaeser (2013). Haughwout et al. (2013) define the
boom period as 2000–2006 and the bust period as 2007–2010. Ferreira and Gyourko (2018) find that the start
of the house price boom was not synchronized across the United States and house prices for each ZIP code also
peaked in different months. Our speculation measure and several economic outcome variables are at the annual
frequency, so we use 2006 as the turning point of housing cycles across regions.
6 However, this measure has limitations. For instance, investors may purchase their houses for vacation purposes.
Non-owner-occupied house purchases also could be affected by demand from renters and new migrants. To
address this issue, we include various local characteristics, such as the fraction of employment in the sectors
of art, entertainment, and recreation, the ratio of renters, as well as the fraction of migrants, as controls in our
analysis.
5253
7 From 2005 to 2006, for a median income household, the marginal capital gains tax rate changed from 9% to
8.7% in the District of Columbia and from 4.983% to 4.764% in Ohio.
8 Even credit rating agencies, such as Moody’s, calculated the credit risk of mortgage-backed securities during the
boom period under the assumption that housing prices would not decline in the near future. In addition, Cheng,
Raina, and Xiong (2014) find that a sample of securitization agents also increased their own exposures to housing
in 2004–2006.
5254
Table 1
Summary statistics and correlations
A. Summary statistics of the key variables
(1) (2) (3)
Variables N Mean SD
Fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases in 2004–2006 3,975 0.136 0.0987
Real house price change in 2001–2003 4,027 0.191 0.135
Real house price change in 2004–2006 4,027 0.278 0.191
Real house price change in 2007–2009 4,027 −0.413 0.278
Per capita income change in 2003–2006 4,027 0.0521 0.125
Per capita income change in 2007–2009 4,026 −0.113 0.0957
some states have extended the capital gains exclusion to secondary homes since
the financial crisis suggests that taxes on capital gains are a relevant margin in
home buyer decisions.
Motivated by this observation, we instrument the fraction of non-owner-
occupied home purchases during the boom period of 2004–2006 with a tax
variable that incorporates the marginal capital gains tax rate across states. This
variable is equal to zero in states with no capital gains taxes and the marginal tax
rate for a median income household in states with capital gains taxes.9 In using
9 Albanesi, Giorgi, and Nosal (2017) provide evidence that real estate investors during the housing boom were
concentrated in the middle and upper echelons of the income distribution. We have also verified that our results
are robust to using the top marginal capital gains tax rate or a dummy indicator variable of whether a state has a
capital gains tax.
5255
Table 1
(Continued)
B. Correlations of non-owner-occupied versus subprime housing purchases with control variables during the
boom period and the p-values of their differences
Fraction of non-owner-occupied Fraction of subprime
Variables home purchases in 2004–2006 mortgages in 2005 p -value
Real house price change in 0.277∗∗∗ 0.383∗∗∗ .000
2004–2006
Per capita income change in 0.206∗∗∗ −0.388∗∗∗ .000
2003–2006
Change in no. of establishments 0.100∗∗∗ −0.066∗∗∗ .000
10 Out-of-state investment home buyers introduce a nuanced issue. A buyer expects to pay taxes on future capital
gains in both states—the state of residence and the state where the home resides—but may receive tax credits
from the state of residence to offset the double tax incidence. The buyer thus pays the higher tax rate between
the two states. We expect this issue to mostly affect ZIP codes close to the state border. In Section B of the
5256
capital gains taxes to provide evidence of the relevance of state capital gains
taxes as an instrument for housing speculation.
For our instrument to be valid, it also needs to satisfy the exclusion restriction
for causality with respect to the housing boom and the subsequent housing bust
and economic contraction.11 While economic activity in a state might be related
to its treatment of state-level personal taxation, our analysis requires only that, in
absence of omitted variables correlated with both taxes and changes in housing
prices, the relative magnitudes of the housing boom and bust and real outcomes
during the Great Recession were not directly driven by variation in state-level
Internet Appendix, we repeat our empirical tests after splitting ZIP codes into two subsamples: (1) ZIP codes
within 50 miles of state borders and (2) ZIP codes further than 50 miles from state borders. Consistent with our
relevance assumption, the impact of housing speculation on housing prices and real outcomes is quantitatively
more pronounced in the second subsample, where there is likely less noise from incorrect assignment of the tax
treatment to non-owner-occupied home purchases. Our results are still quantitatively and statistically significant
for the first subsample, despite this classification issue.
11 One concern is that although homeowners can exclude up to $250,000 ($500,000 per couple) of capital gains
from the sale of their primary residence, the capital gains taxes could still affect households’ primary home
demand. As we construct our speculation measure as the fraction of non-owner-occupied homes in all home
purchases, we filter out the potential effect of the primary home demand to mitigate this concern.
12 We use the level of, rather than the change in, state capital gains taxes as our instrument. The level was stable
during the period of 2004–2006. Although the change in taxation might directly shock housing markets and
local economies, the level of state capital gains taxation likely affected only housing speculators’ decisions when
widespread optimism arose during the boom period.
5257
13 We report the results for this presample period, because the IRS data start from 1998. The results are also
insignificant for the variables available in the ZIP Code Business Patterns database since 1994.
14 Specifically, we run the state-level panel regressions of marginal state capital gains tax rate for $50,000 in income
(in 2005 USD) on contemporaneous, lagged (1 or 5 years), or leading (1 or 5 years) changes in housing prices,
and economic performance, including wages and salaries, number of establishments, employment, per capita
income, and unemployment rate. We also control for the corporate tax rate, sales tax rate, and year fixed effects.
We find similar results for the $10,000, $25,000, $75,000, and $100,000 income brackets. We also find similar
results if, instead of 1- and 5-year leads and lags, we use 2, 3, or 4 years. These state-level variables come from
Serrato and Zidar (2018) and NBER TAXISM.
15 Haughwout et al. (2011) use the FRBNY Consumer Credit Panel to determine housing investors based on the
number of first-lien mortgage accounts that appear on their credit reports. Their proprietary data are more reliable
than the HMDA data. Chinco and Mayer (2016) identify out-of-town second home buyers by distinguishing
between the property and tax bill mailing addresses in transaction deeds. These data, however, are not as
comprehensive as the HMDA data with which we are able to conduct a nationwide analysis of housing markets.
5258
35%
Share of non-owner-occupied home purchases
30%
25%
5%
0%
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Year
Figure 1
Fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases
This figure plots the share of non-owner-occupied home purchases for the United States and three cities, New
York, Las Vegas, and Charlotte. The fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases in each city is computed
from the “Home Mortgage Disclosure Act” data set.
both types of home purchases are at least partially influenced by the motive to
speculate on housing price appreciation, which became a national phenomenon
in the low-interest-rate environment of the mid-2000s. Among the three cities,
Las Vegas had the highest fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases,
which rose from a level 17.77% in 2000 to 29.41% in 2005, and then dropped
back down to 17.77% in 2008. New York had the lowest fraction, which, while
having a synchronous rise and fall with the other two cities, remained below
7% during this period.
One may be concerned that our measure of speculation has substantial
measurement error, because it does not include investment home purchases
made in cash, and there is evidence of systematic misreporting of owner
occupancy by banks to MBS investors (see, for instance, Piskorski, Seru, and
Witkin 2015). Consistent with the intuition that our measure of speculation
underestimates the true level of speculation in a ZIP code, Table C2 in Section
C of the Internet Appendix confirms that the ordinary least squares (OLS)
estimates of all our coefficients of interest are biased downward compared
to their IV counterparts. To address the potential issue that our results may
be driven by fraud from misreporting, rather than speculation itself, we add
the misreporting measure from Piskorski, Seru, and Witkin (2015), which
measures the mean fraction of loans in a ZIP code with undeclared second
liens or nonowner occupancy status, as a control in all our main regressions in
Section D of the Internet Appendix.16
16 We do not control for it in our main tables because of the loss of ZIP code observations in matching the data.
5259
17 Table C1 in Section C of the Internet Appendix reports reduced-form regressions of house price changes and all
our economic outcomes during the cycle on the tax instrument. Although the coefficients are not economically
interpretable in the context of housing speculation, their statistical significance provides evidence of an economic
link between our tax instrument and economic outcomes, which is central for our IV regressions.
18 Mian, Sufi, and Trebbi (2015) used a similar ZIP-code-level analysis around state borders with different
foreclosure laws to justify state judicial requirements as an instrument for foreclosures. They find a jump in
the foreclosure rate at the border between a judicial state and a nonjudicial state.
5260
Panel A of Table 2 tests for a jump across borders in the fraction of non-
owner-occupied home purchases from 2004 to 2006 and in the fraction of
subprime mortgages in 2005 and reveals that the dummy for whether the
state has capital gains taxes significantly negatively predicts our measure of
speculation, but does not affect subprime credit expansion. The fraction of non-
owner-occupied home purchases jumps by 4.9%, and this economic magnitude
is substantial relative to its mean of 13.6% and standard deviation of 9.9%.
Panel A of Figure 3 graphically confirms a discontinuous jump in the fraction
of non-owner-occupied home purchases at the state borders when plotting the
19 All our results are quantitatively similar and remain significant if we instead use Zillow housing price indices as
our measure of local housing prices. Section F of the Internet Appendix reports these results.
5261
Table 2
ZIP codes near borders of states without capital gains taxes
A.
(1) (2)
Fraction of non-owner-occupied Fraction of subprime
home purchases in 2004–2006 mortgages in 2005
Dummy for states with −0.0487∗∗ 0.00182
capital gains tax (0.0212) (0.0248)
Distance −2.241∗∗ 0.763
(1.039) (0.964)
Distance squared −40.59∗ −37.77∗
5262
0.2
Fraction of Non-owner-occupied homes
0.15
0.1
in 2004-06
0.05
-0.05
-0.1
-50 -30 -10 10 30 50
Miles from border
B Subprime mortgages
0.2
Fraction of subprime mortgages in 2005
0.15
0.1
0.05
-0.05
-0.1
-0.15
-0.2
-50 -30 -10 10 30 50
Miles from border
Figure 3
ZIP codes near borders of states without capital gains taxes
This figure plots the fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases in 2004–2006 (panel A) and the fraction
of subprime mortgages in 2005 (panel B) in ZIP codes near borders of states without capital gains taxes. The
variables of interests are regressed on dummies indicating each 1-mile distance from the border (dummies are
negative for neighboring states with capital gains taxes) and state-border*10-mile strip fixed effects. The figure
plots the coefficients on the distance dummies.
level are available from the Internal Revenue Service (IRS). The IRS does
not, however, provide data for 2000 and 2003. We therefore use the data
for 2002 and 2006 to calculate the changes during the boom period and the
5263
250
150
New York
Las Vegas
100
Charloe
50 US
Figure 4
Case-Shiller home price indices
This figure plots the Case-Shiller home price indices for the United States and three cities, New York, Las Vegas,
and Charlotte. The price index is deflated by the CPI and normalized to 100 in 2000.
changes from 2001 to 2002 for the preboom period. Data about annual total
employment, annual payroll, and the number of establishments at the ZIP code
level are available from the ZIP Code Business Patterns database. We include
both resident income and annual payroll from employers because, as argued by
Mian and Sufi (2009), residents in a certain area do not necessarily work in the
same place that they live. The change in per capita income has a mean of 5.2%
in 2003–2006 and a mean of -11.3% in 2007–2009, which is consistent with the
dramatic economic expansion and recession during the boom and bust period.
Similarly, the employment change has a mean of 7.1% (-8.3%), the change in
the number of establishments has a mean of 6.4% (-3.8%), and the real payroll
change has a mean of 8.7% (-10.0%) in 2004–2006 (2007–2009).
ZIP Code Business Patterns database also provides employment data by
establishment size and by industry. For our analysis, we are interested in the
construction industry as it is directly related to the supply side of housing
markets. We also follow Mian and Sufi (2014) to identify nontradable industries
because they produce nontradable goods and services, which reflect the strength
of local demand. Alternatively, we examine the retail and restaurant industries,
which rely on local consumption.
5264
6%
Building permits in 2004 to 2006 relave
5%
to the housing units in 2000
4%
New York
3%
Las Vegas
2% Charloe
0%
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Year
Figure 5
New housing supply
This figure depicts building permits in 2000 to 2010 relative to the housing units in 2000 for the United States
and three cities, New York, Las Vegas, and Charlotte.
20 Authorization to start is a largely irreversible process, with housing starts being only 2.5% lower than building
permits at the aggregate level, according to https://www.census.gov/construction/nrc/nrcdatarelationships.html,
the Web site of the Census Bureau. Moreover, the delay between authorization and housing start is relatively
short, on average less than 1 month, according to https://www.census.gov/construction/nrc/lengthoftime.html.
These facts suggest that building permits are an appropriate measure of new housing supply.
21 Our results for new housing supply are robust to allocating new building permits at the county level to ZIP codes,
according to the fraction of employment in residential construction in 2000.
5265
the rise and fall of non-owner-occupied home purchases and the housing price
cycle.
22 We control for these variables only in 2005, because we use the subprime mortgage fraction in 2005. The results
are unaffected if we instead choose these controls in 2004–2006.
23 We acknowledge that misreporting is common in mortgage data, as emphasized in Griffin and Maturana (2015,
2016). For example, recent studies, such as those by Avery et al. (2012), Blackburn and Vermilyea (2012), and
Mian and Sufi (2015), cast doubt on the accuracy of HMDA data and, in particular, find that the income variable
could be overstated by home buyers. For this reason, we use income data from the IRS and control for the
misreporting measure from Piskorski, Seru, and Witkin (2015) for robustness.
24 The Saiz (2010) measure is not, however, without its issues. Davidoff (2015), for instance, argues that the Saiz
measure is a poor instrument for housing prices, because it is correlated with many variables related to housing
demand.
5266
25 In Section G of the Internet Appendix, we rerun all our regressions for the sample excluding the four sand states
for robustness. It is reassuring that our results are not affected by their exclusion.
5267
1
.8
.6
0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Fraction of subprime mortgages in 2005
Figure 6
Speculation and subprime households
This figure plots the fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases in 2004 to 2006 against the fraction of
subprime mortgages in 2005 at the ZIP code level.
3. Economic Consequences
In this section, we examine the cross-section of housing speculation during the
boom period of 2004–2006, and its economic consequences during both the
boom period and the subsequent bust period of 2007–2009.
5268
5269
A
.8
.6
.4
0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
Fraction of Non-Owner-Occupied Home Purchases in 2004-06
B
0
-.5 -1
-1.5
-2
0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
Fraction of Non-Owner-Occupied Home Purchases in 2004-06
Figure 7
Speculation and housing price cycle
These figures plot the real housing price change during the boom period of 2004 to 2006 (panel A) and the bust
period of 2007 to 2009 (panel B) against the fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases in 2004 to 2006 at
the ZIP code level.
5270
Table 3
Speculation and housing price cycles
(1) (2) (3)
Fraction of non-owner- Real house Real house
occupied home purchases price change price change
in 2004–2006 in 2004–2006 in 2007–2009
State capital gains tax rate for −0.677∗∗
median income
(0.269)
Fraction of non-owner-occupied 2.685∗∗ −3.785∗∗∗
home purchases in 2004–2006
5271
Table 3
(Continued)
(1) (2) (3)
Fraction of immigrants in 2000 0.191∗∗∗ −0.412 0.401
(0.0346) (0.289) (0.387)
Fraction of employment in arts 0.742∗∗∗ −1.983∗∗ 2.339∗∗∗
entertainment and recreation in
2000
(0.117) (0.840) (0.798)
Dummy for states with 0.0123 −0.0155 0.0976∗
nonrecourse mortgage law
where the left-hand variable is the housing price change during either the boom
period of 2004–2006 or the bust period of 2007–2009, and Speculationi,boom is
the projected housing speculation from the first-stage regression. We also add
the same control variables from the first-stage regression.
Column 2 of Table 3 shows that the IV coefficient estimate of the impact
of housing speculation on housing prices during the boom is significantly
positive, both statistically and in its economic magnitude: a 1-standard-
deviation increase in the fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases across
ZIP codes causes a substantial price increase of 26.5%. Column 3 of Table 3
shows the IV estimate of the impact of housing speculation on the housing price
contraction during the bust is significantly negative, both statistically and in its
economic magnitude: a 1-standard-deviation increase in the fraction of non-
owner-occupied home purchases across ZIP codes translates to a substantial
price decline of 37.4%. Taken together, our analysis establishes a causal link
between housing speculation during the boom period of 2004–2006 and the
housing boom and bust cycle of 2004–2009.
What drove housing speculation during the boom period? We now examine
extrapolative expectations as a driver of housing speculation. We hypothesize
5272
Table 4
Extrapolation and housing speculation
(1) (2)
Fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases in 2004–2006
Real house 0.0231 0.229∗∗∗
price change in 2001–2003 (0.0574) (0.0508)
Interaction −5.413∗∗∗
(0.986)
State capital 0.157
gain tax rate for median income (0.288)
Speculationi,boom
= a +bPricei,pre−boom +cTax i +dPricei,pre−boom ·Tax i +Controlsi +i ,
(3)
where Speculationi,boom is the fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases
in ZIP code i during the boom period of 2004–2006 and Pricei,pre−boom refers
to the cumulative housing price change during the preboom period of 2001–
2003. We also interact Pricei,pre−boom with the capital gains tax rate Tax i .
Lastly, we also control for a host of local fundamental variables during the
preboom period.
Table 4 displays the results on extrapolation. Without including the state
capital gains tax rate, Column 1 shows positive though statistically insignificant
relationship between housing speculation and the lagged housing price change.
In contrast, when we introduce the state capital gains tax rate into the
regression, as specified in Equation (3). Column 2 shows that, across ZIP codes,
5273
housing price increases during the preboom period significantly predict higher
fractions of non-owner-occupied home purchases during the boom period.
More importantly, housing speculation at the ZIP code level in states with
less capital gains taxes reacted more strongly to the preboom housing price
increase, and this relation is statistically significant at the 1% level.26 This
finding thus provides evidence that housing speculation, anchored on past house
price changes, contributed a nonfundamental source of housing demand during
the boom, especially in areas more prone to speculative behavior.27 This result
also indicates the important role played by state capital gains taxation in shaping
26 The Frisch-Waugh theorem offers an alternative interpretation of our results. The coefficient on past housing prices
and its interaction with the tax instrument is equivalent to regressing the residual from regressing the fraction of
non-owner-occupied home purchases on fundamentals on the residuals from regressing past housing prices and
its interaction on fundamentals. The OLS coefficients therefore capture the responsiveness of nonfundamental
housing demand to past housing price growth that is orthogonal to fundamentals and its interaction with the tax
instrument.
27 Consistent with our results, Wheaton and Nechayev (2008) show that a regression forecasting housing price
appreciation systematically underestimates the realized housing price growth between 1998 and 2005 and that
these forecast errors are positively correlated with the percentage of home sales attributed to investors and second
home buyers within an MSA.
5274
Table 5
Real effects of housing speculation
A. The boom period
(Continued)
5275
Table 5
(Continued)
B. The bust period
(Continued)
5276
Table 5
(Continued)
(1) (2) (3) (4)
This table reports the two-stage least squares regressions of economic outcomes in 2004–2006 (panel A) and in
2007–2009 (panel B) on the fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases in 2004–2006 instrumented with
the state capital gains tax rate for the median income. All regressions control for the supply elasticity measure,
the fraction of subprime mortgages in 2005, the mortgage denial rate in 2005, the fraction of GSE mortgages in
2005, the mortgage denial rate for non-owner-occupied mortgages in 2005, the fraction of GSE mortgages for
non-owner-occupied mortgages in 2005, population change in 2003–2006, per capita income change in 2003–
2006, the change in the number of establishments in 2004–2006, real payroll change in 2004–2006, employment
change in 2004–2006, the natural logarithm of population in 2000, the fraction of the college educated in 2000,
the fraction of the employed in 2000, the fraction of workforce in 2000, median household income in 2000,
poverty rate in 2000, urban rate in 2000, the fraction of white residents in 2000, the fraction of employment in
arts, entertainment, and recreation in 2000, the fraction of renters in 2000, the fraction of immigrants in 2000,
the dummy for states with nonrecourse mortgage law, and the dummy of sand states. Observations are weighted
by the number of households. Standard errors are clustered at the state level. *p <.1; **p <.05; ***p <.01.
4, also increase by 12.9% and 8.4%, respectively. Finally, the change in the
number of establishments, shown in Column 2, is the most modest, although
the effect is still economically meaningful: a 1-standard-deviation increase in
the fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases across ZIP codes translates
to an increase of 6.8% in the number of establishments.
Panel B of Table 5 reports the results of regressing our measures of economic
activity in the bust period of 2007–2009 on the fraction of non-owner-occupied
home purchases during the boom period of 2004–2006, instrumented by our
tax rate variable. Housing speculation is negatively associated with all four
measures of economic consequences at the 1% significance level during the
bust. Among these measures, real payroll, which is shown in Column 3, is most
heavily affected by local housing speculation during the boom: a 1-standard-
deviation increase in the fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases across
ZIP codes corresponds to a substantial drop of 15.4% in real payroll. The same
increase in housing speculation also corresponds to substantial drops of 7.8%
in income per capita, 8.7% in the number of establishments, and 14.6% in
employment, as shown in Columns 1, 2, and 4, respectively. The variation
across ZIP codes in their economic responses, consequently, reflects not only
differences in the deterioration of local fundamentals and firm adjustment costs
of employment, wages, and establishments but also differences in exposure to
housing speculation during the boom.
As shown in Tables 3 and 5, some of these control variables are also
highly significant. In particular, the fraction of subprime mortgages in 2005
5277
is significantly correlated with the magnitudes of the housing price boom and
bust, as well as our four measures of the local economic downturn during the
bust period, consistent with the findings of Mian and Sufi (2009, 2014).
In addition to the results presented here, we also report robustness analyses
in the Internet Appendix. As two of the four sand states, Florida and Nevada,
have no capital gains taxes, this raises a potential concern that the effect of
housing speculation on the price increase during the boom, and decline during
the bust, might be driven by these two states. Section G of the Internet Appendix
invalidates this concern by repeating Tables 3 and 5 but excluding the four
4. Transmission Mechanisms
Having demonstrated a causal relationship between housing speculation during
the boom period and the decline in local economic activity during the bust, we
now investigate several potential transmission mechanisms by which housing
speculation propagated to the real economy during 2007–2009.
5278
.5
.4
.3
0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Fraction of Non-Owner-Occupied Home Purchases in 2004-06
Figure 8
Speculation and new housing supply
This figure plots building permits in 2004 to 2006 relative to the number of housing units in 2000 against the
fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases in 2004 to 2006 at the county level.
5279
Table 6
Speculation and new housing supply
(1) (2)
Fraction of non-owner- Building permits in 2004–2006
occupied home purchases relative to the housing
in 2004–2006 units in 2000
State capital gains tax rate for −0.822∗∗∗
median income (0.138)
Fraction of non-owner-occupied 0.428∗∗∗
home purchases in 2004–2006 (0.105)
Constant 0.656∗∗∗ −0.263∗∗
5280
Table 7
Effects of housing speculation on construction and nonconstruction sectors
A. The boom period
(1) (2)
Construction employment Nonconstruction employment
change in 2004–2006 change in 2004–2006
Fraction of non-owner-occupied 2.543∗∗∗ 0.624∗∗∗
home purchases in 2004–2006 (0.811) (0.239)
Constant −0.676 −0.477∗∗∗
(0.513) (0.123)
Controls Yes Yes
5281
may affect their consumption. As suggested by Mian, Rao, and Sufi (2013)
and Mian and Sufi (2014), the shock to household consumption would, in
turn, drive the demand for local services. Thus, housing speculation during the
boom may also lead to an economic cycle through this local demand channel.
As such, we expect housing speculation during the boom to have stronger
explanatory power for economic outcomes in industries that are driven by local
demand.
To examine this local demand channel, we use the classification of
nontradable and tradable industries from Mian and Sufi (2014), 28 who define
28 For the detailed classification, refer to appendix Table 1 of Mian and Sufi (2014).
5282
Table 8
Effect of housing speculation: Demand channel
A. The boom period
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Employment Employment Retail and Employment change
change change restaurant in industries other
in nontradable in tradable employment than retail and
industries in industries in change in restaurant in
2004–2006 2004–2006 2004–2006 2004–2006
Fraction of non- owner-occupied home 0.889∗∗∗ 0.558 0.904∗∗∗ 0.448
purchases in 2004–2006 (0.265) (0.685) (0.261) (0.274)
5283
likely complementary, and we are reassured at finding that both are significant
in contributing to the severity of the local recessions during the bust.29
5. Conclusion
In this paper, we provide evidence that housing speculation, as measured by the
fraction of non-owner-occupied home purchases, arose from extrapolation by
speculators of past housing price changes. We document how this speculation
during the boom period of 2004–2006 had positive economic consequences
References
Albanesi, S., G. D. Giorgi, and J. Nosal. 2017. Credit growth and the financial crisis: A new narrative. Mimeo,
University of Pittsburgh, Geneva School of Economics and Management, and Boston College.
Adelino, M., A. Schoar, and F. Severino. 2015. House prices, collateral, and self-employment. Journal of
Financial Economics 117:288–306.
Avery, R. B., N. Bhutta, K. Brevoort, and G. B. Canner. 2012. The mortgage market in 2011: Highlights from
data reported under the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act. Federal Reserve Bulletin 98:1–46.
Barlevy, G., and J. D. M. Fisher. 2011. Mortgage choice and housing speculation. Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago.
Bayer, P., C. Geissler, K. Mangum, and J. W. Roberts. 2015. Speculators and middlemen: The strategy and
performance of investors in the housing market. Mimeo, Duke University, Georgia State University, ISO New
England, and NBER.
Blackburn, M. K. L., and T. Vermilyea. 2012. The prevalence and impact of misstated incomes on mortgage loan
applications. Journal of Housing Economics 21:151–68.
Case, K. E., and R. J. Shiller. 2003. Is there a bubble in the housing market? Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 2003:299–362.
29 Although we focus on only two channels, the literature has identified several other potential transmission
mechanisms. By reducing the collateral value of housing (a widely used collateral for firms to raise debt
financing), housing speculation may have affected firms’ access to credit during the housing bust, as studied
in Adelino, Schoar, and Severino (2015) and Schmalz, Sraer, and Thesmar (2017). Another channel is through
the impairment of intermediary balance sheets of local banks during the bust, which may have prevented them
from lending to local firms, as highlighted in Gan (2007) and He and Krishnamurthy (2013). Housing speculation
may also affect local economic activity through a crowding out effect. By encumbering mortgage financing from
local banks, housing speculation may have crowded out limited bank financing to nonhousing investment, as
suggested by Chakraborty, Goldstein, and MacKinlay (2018). We leave it to future research to analyze these
potentially important channels.
5284
Case, K. E., and R. J. Shiller, and A. Thompson. 2012. What have they been thinking? Homebuyer behavior in
hot and cold markets. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 45:265–315.
———. 2015. What have they been thinking? Homebuyer behavior in hot and cold markets — A 2014 update.
Discussion Paper, Cowles Foundation.
Chakraborty, I., I. Goldstein, and A. MacKinlay. 2018. Housing price booms and crowding-out effects in bank
lending. Review of Financial Studies 31:2806–53.
Charles, K. K., E. Hurst, and M. J. Notowidigdo. 2016a. Housing booms and busts, labor market opportunities,
and college attendance. Mimeo, University of Chicago and Northwestern.
Chen, T., L. X. Liu, W. Xiong, and L. Zhou. 2016. The speculation channel and crowding out channel: Real
estate shocks and corporate investment in China. Mimeo, Princeton University.
Cheng, I. H., S. Raina, and W. Xiong. 2014. Wall Street and the housing bubble. American Economic Review
104:2797–829.
Chinco, A., and C. Mayer. 2016. Misinformed speculators and mispricing in the housing market. Review of
Financial Studies 29:486–522.
Choi, H. S., H. G. Hong, J. D. Kubik, and J. P. Thompson. 2016. Sand states and the U.S. housing crisis. Mimeo,
Singapore School of Management, Columbia University, Syracuse University, and Federal Reserve Board.
Da, Z., M. Warachka, and H. Yun. 2016. Fiscal policy, consumption risk, and stock returns: Evidence from U.S.
states. Mimeo, University of Notre Dame, University of San Diego, and Michigan State University.
Davidoff, T. 2015. Supply constraints are not valid instrumental variables for home prices because they are
correlated with many demand factors. Mimeo, UBC.
DeFusco, A. A., C. G. Nathanson, and E. Zwick. 2017. Speculative dynamics of prices and volume. Mimeo,
Kellogg School of Management and University of Chicago Booth.
Dobbie, W., and P. Goldsmith-Pinkham. 2014. Debtor protections and the Great Recession. Working Paper.
Fajgelbaum, P. D., E. Morales, J. C. S. Serrato, and O. M. Zidar. 2019. State taxes and spatial misallocation.
Review of Economic Studies 86:333–76.
Favara, G., and J. Imbs. 2015. Credit supply and the price of housing. American Economic Review 105:958–92.
Favilukis, J., S. Ludvigson, and S. V. Nieuwerburgh. 2017. Macroeconomic implications of housing wealth,
housing finance, and limited risk-sharing in general equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy 125:140–223.
Ferreira, F., and J. Gyourko. 2018. Anatomy of the beginning of the housing boom: US neighborhoods and
metropolitan areas. Mimeo, NBER.
Gale, W. G., A. Krupkin, and K. S. Reuben. 2015. The relationship between taxes and growth at the state level:
New evidence. Mimeo, Brookings Institute.
Gan, J. 2007. The real effects of asset market bubbles: Loan- and firm-level evidence of a lending channel. Review
of Financial Studies 20:1941–73.
Glaeser, E. L. 2013. A nation of gamblers: Real estate speculation and American history. American Economic
Review Papers and Proceedings 103:1–42.
Glaeser, E. L., J. Gyourko, and A. Saiz. 2008. Housing supply and housing bubbles. Journal of Urban Economics
64:198–217.
Glaeser, E. L., and C. G. Nathanson. 2017. An extrapolative model of house price dynamics. Journal of Financial
Economics 126:147–70.
Griffin, J. M., and G. Maturana. 2016. Who facilitated misreporting in securitized loans? Review of Financial
Studies 29:384–419.
5285
———. 2016. Did dubious mortgage origination practices distort house prices? Review of Financial Studies
29:1671–708.
Haughwout, A., D. Lee, J. S. Tracy, and W. van der Klaauw. 2011. Real estate investors, the leverage cycle, and
the housing market crisis. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports.
Haughwout, A., R. W. Peach, J. Sporn, and J. Tracy. 2013. The supply side of the housing boom and bust of
the 2000s. In Housing and the financial crisis, eds. E. L. Glaeser, and T. Sinai, 69–104. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
He, Z., and A. Krishnamurthy. 2013. Intermediary asset pricing. American Economic Review 103:732–70.
Hurst, E., B. J. Keys, A. Seru, and J. S. Vavra. 2016. Regional redistribution through the US mortgage market.
American Economic Review 106:2982–3028.
Justiano, A., G. Primiceri, and A. Tambolatti. 2017. Credit supply and the housing boom. Mimeo, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago and Northwestern University.
Kaplan, G., K. Mitman, and G. L. Violante. 2017. The housing boom and bust: Model meets evidence. Mimeo,
University of Chicago, Stockholm University, and Princeton University.
Keys, B. J., T. Mukherjee, A. Seru, and V. Vig. 2009. Financial regulation and securitization: Evidence from
subprime mortgage loans. Journal of Monetary Economics 56:700–720.
———. 2010. Did securitization lead to lax screening? Evidence from subprime loans. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 12:307–62.
Landvoigt, T., M. Piazzesi, and M. Schneider. 2015. The housing market(s) of San Diego. American Economic
Review 105:1371–407.
Mayer, C., and T. Sinai. 2009. U.S. House price dynamics and behavioral finance. In Policy making insights from
behavioral economics, eds. C. L. Foote, L. Goette, and S. Meier, 261–308. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston.
Mian, A., K. Rao, and A. Sufi. 2013. Household balance sheets, consumption, and the economic slump. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 128:1687–726.
Mian, A., and A. Sufi. 2009. The consequences of mortgage credit expansion: Evidence from the U.S. mortgage
default crisis. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124:1449–96.
———. 2010. Household leverage and the recession of 2007-09. IMF Economic Review 58:74–117.
———. 2011. House prices, home equity-based borrowing, and the US household leverage crisis. American
Economic Review 101:2132–56.
———. 2014. What explains the 2007–2009 drop in employment? Econometrica 82:2197–223.
———. 2015. Fraudulent income oversight on mortgage applications during the credit expansion of 2002 to
2005. Mimeo, University of Chicago and Princeton University.
Mian, A., A. Sufi, and F. Trebbi. 2015. Foreclosures, house prices, and the real economy. Journal of Finance
70:2587–634.
Nathanson, C. G., and E. Zwick. 2017. Arrested development: Theory and evidence of supply-side speculation
in the housing market. Mimeo, University of Chicago and Northwestern University.
Nam, T. Y., and S. Oh. 2016. Non-recourse mortgage law and housing speculation. Mimeo, OCC and Peking
University.
National Association of Realtors. 2015. Investment and vacation home buyers survey 2015.
5286
Piazzesi, M., and M. Schneider. 2009. Momentum traders in the housing market: Survey evidence and a search
model. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 99:406–11.
Piskorski, T., A. Seru, and J. Witkin. 2015. Asset quality misrepresentation by financial intermediaries: Evidence
from the RMBS market. Journal of Finance 70:2635–78.
Purnanandam, A. 2011. Originate-to-distribute model and the subprime mortgage crisis. Review of Financial
Studies 24:1881–915.
Rognlie, M., A. Shleifer, and A. Simsek. 2018. Investment hangover and the great recession. American Economic
Journal: Macroeconomics 10(2): 113-53.
Schmalz, M. C., D. A. Sraer, and D. Thesmar. 2017. Housing collateral and entrepreneurship. Journal of Finance
72:99–132.
Serrato, J. C. S., and O. Zidar. 2018. The structure of state corporate taxation and its impact on state tax revenues
and economic activity. Journal of Public Economics 167:158–76.
Shan, H. 2011. The effect of capital gains taxation on home sales: Evidence from the Taxpayer Relief Act of
1997. Journal of Public Economics 95:177–88.
Shiller, R. J. 2009. Unlearned lessons from the housing bubble. In Economicists’ voice, eds. A. Belke and G.
Schnabl, 1553–3832. Berlin, Germany: Walter de Gruyte.
Soo, C. K. 2018. Quantifying sentiment with news media across local housing markets. Review of Financial
Studies 31:3689–719.
Walden, M. L. 2014. Recovery from the Great Recession: Explaining differences among states. Journal of
Regional and Policy Analysis 44:166–74.
Wheaton, W., and G. Nechayev. 2008. The 1998-2005 housing “bubble” and the current “correction”: What’s
different this time? Journal of Real Estate Research 30:1–26.
5287